Question:
How was the religion and economy in europe 1600-1700?PLZ HELP?
The dude
2006-11-26 03:36:45 UTC
How was the religion and economy in europe 1600-1700?
Ten answers:
rdenig_male
2006-11-26 04:54:20 UTC
The religion was Catholic in France, Spain, Portugal and Greece. In The Netherlands and in England it was Protestant. Germany was not yet a nation, but numerous states, some of which were Catholic and some Protestant (Lutheran). This led to tensions and war. The Catholic inclined Stuart kings of England looked to France for inspiration - after Charles I had been executed, his son, the future Charles II took refuge in France. When James II ascended the throne as a Catholic there were tensions between him and Parliament which led to his eventual overthrow and the invitation to the Protestant William of Orange and his wife Mary to become joint monarchs. France began to take a harder line against Protestants during the century with Louis XIV repealing the Edict of Nantes which allowed religious toleration. Generally the century, throughout Europe, was not noted for toleration anywhere with constant conflict between Catholic and.Protestant. I'll leave someone else to comment on economy.
Susan
2016-03-13 04:19:09 UTC
Hmm Norway, Netherlands, Cyprus they're the good ones, Latvia no way ahaha just awful country in UK things are tough. Poland is very good in economy now when everyones economy going down theires going up. Hmm well that's what I gotta say in future I'm going to study to USA or Netherlands :)
Josephine
2006-11-26 06:29:26 UTC
The most important thing is what no one mentioned and its the 30 years war 1618-1648 between the catholics and protestants

it ruined Europe and it gave the protestants a good share of the Catholic wealth in land and other commodities. You can read about this war in numerous sites so here is the google site that lists all sites:



http://www.google.com/search?q=Thirty+years+war&sourceid=ie7&rls=com.microsoft:en-US&ie=utf8&oe=utf8
2014-09-24 13:22:11 UTC
If you want to earn money with binary trading and you aren't a big expert you definitely need some kind of support. I use a software called "autobinary signals" and I earning good money with it. Here you can find all the details and also some video proofs: http://tradingsignal.toptips.org
2014-12-18 18:39:36 UTC
the best trading software http://tradingsolution.info

i have attended a lot of seminars, read counless books on forex trading and it all cost me thousands of dollars. the worst thing was i blew up my first account. after that i opened another account and the same thing happened again. i started to wonder why i couldn,t make any money in forex trading. at first i thought i knew everything about trading. finally i found that the main problem i have was i did not have the right mental in trading. as we know that psychology has great impact on our trading result. apart from psychology issue, there is another problem that we have to address. they are money management, market analysis, and entry/exit rules. to me money management is important in trading. i opened another account and start to trade profitably after i learnt from my past mistake. i don't trade emotionally anymore.

if you are serious about trading you need to address your weakness and try to fix it. no forex guru can make you Professional trader unless you want to learn from your mistake.
2006-11-26 03:39:39 UTC
europe is too much of a mix of culture and race to answer this accurately.... different countries were at different stages... especially as there always was some war or invasion on the offing.
2016-08-23 15:24:37 UTC
I was wondering much the same question
2016-09-21 06:20:19 UTC
This is unclear to me too
Golda
2016-08-09 00:08:31 UTC
Good question, hope you find your answer
rvp
2006-11-26 04:13:51 UTC
The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional

Change and Economic Growth∗

Daron Acemoglu

Department of Economics, MIT

Simon Johnson

Sloan School of Management, MIT

James Robinson

Departments of Political Science and Economics, Berkeley

May 4, 2004

∗We thank Thomas Becker and Rui Pedro Esteves for outstanding research assistance and Josh

Angrist, Abhijit Banerjee, Timothy Besley, Dora Costa, Jan de Vries, Stanley Engerman, Philip Hoff-

man, Peter Lindert, Sebasti´an Mazzuca, Joel Mokyr, Larry Neal, Steve Pincus, Christina Romer,

David Romer, Andrei Shleifer, Alan Taylor, Hans-Joachim Voth, two anonymous referees, and seminar

participants at Berkeley, the Canadian Institute of Advanced Research, Chicago Business School and

Political Science, George Mason University, Harvard Business School, the Harvard Economic History

Seminar, the London School of Economics, MIT, the National Bureau of Economic Research economic

history, inequality and economic growth groups, New York University and Princeton for comments and

suggestions.

1

The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade,

Institutional Change and Economic Growth

Abstract

This paper documents that the Rise of Western Europe between 1500 and 1850 is

largely accounted for by the growth of European nations with access to the Atlantic and,

in particular, by those that engaged in colonialism and transoceanic trade. Significant

variation in economic performance among Atlantic trading nations is explained by the

fact that countries with relatively non-absolutist initial institutions experienced faster

growth.

We suggest that Atlantic trade and colonialism affected Europe not only directly, but

also indirectly by inducing institutional changes. In particular, where initial political

institutions placed significant checks on the monarchy, the growth of New World and

Asian trade after 1500 strengthened merchant groups in favor of constraining the power

of the monarchy further, and enabled them to demand and obtain changes in institutions

to protect their property rights. These induced changes in political institutions were

central to the subsequent process of economic growth. In contrast, when initial political

institutions were more absolutist, trade was monopolized by the crown and groups loyal

to the monarchy, and a strong coalition in favor of institutional change failed to emerge.

Keywords: Colonialism, Economic Growth, Institutions, Political Economy, Social

Conflict, Trade.

JEL Numbers: O10, F10, P10, N13.

2

The world we live in–both our material standards of living and our society–was

shaped by the process of rapid economic growth that started in 19th-century Western

Europe. The origins of this rapid economic growth and the associated Industrial Revolution

are generally considered to lie in the economic, political and social development of

Western Europe over the preceding centuries. In fact, between 1500 and 1800, Western

Europe experienced a historically unprecedented period of sustained growth, perhaps

the “First Great Divergence,” making this area substantially richer than Asia and Eastern

Europe by the beginning of the 19th century. There is little agreement however on

why this process of growth took place in Western Europe and why it started in the 16th

century.

This paper establishes a major fact related to the patterns of economic growth in

Western Europe during this era, develops a hypothesis on the origins of the Rise of

(Western) Europe, and provides historical and econometric evidence on some of the

implications of this hypothesis.

The major fact we document is that the differential growth of Western Europe during

the 16th, 17th, 18th and early 19th centuries is almost entirely accounted for by

the differential growth of nations with access to the Atlantic and of Atlantic traders.

Throughout the paper, the term Atlantic trader refers to Britain, France, the Netherlands,

Portugal and Spain, which were the nations most directly involved in trade and

colonialism with the New World and Asia; Atlantic trade, in turn, means trade with the

New World as well as trade with Asia via the Atlantic, and includes colonialism- and

slavery-related activities as well as trade.1 The differential growth of Atlantic traders

suggests a close link between Atlantic trade and the First Great Divergence. In fact, it

appears that the Rise of Europe between 1500 and 1850 is largely the Rise of Atlantic

Europe, and is quite different in nature from pre-1500 European growth.

Not all societies with access to the Atlantic show the same pattern of growth, however.

The data suggest an important interaction between medieval political institutions and

access to the Atlantic: the more rapid economic growth took place in societies with

relatively non-absolutist initial (pre-1500) institutions, most notably in Britain and the

Netherlands. In contrast, countries where the monarchy was highly absolutist, such as

1Atlantic trade opportunities became available only during the late 15th century, thanks to the

discovery of the New World and the passage to Asia around the Cape of Good Hope. These discoveries

resulted from a series of innovations in ship technology, primarily pioneered by the Portuguese, that

changed the rigging and hull design of ships and developed knowledge of oceanic navigation.

1

Spain and Portugal, experienced only limited growth in the subsequent centuries, while

areas lacking easy access to the Atlantic, even such non-absolutist states as Venice and

Genoa, did not experience any direct or indirect benefits from Atlantic trade.

Figures 1 and 2 illustrate the central fact of this paper. Figure 1 Panel A shows

that urbanization in Western Europe grew significantly faster than in Eastern Europe

after 1500.2 Panel B of Figure 1 shows that these differential trends are due in large

part to the growth of Atlantic traders. The rest of Western Europe had a relatively high

average urbanization rate of 10 percent in 1300 (and 11.4 percent in 1500), but grew at

approximately the same rate as Eastern Europe from 1500 to 1850, by a factor of less

than 2, to reach 17.0 percent in 1850. In contrast, Atlantic traders started with a lower

average urbanization rate of 8.0 percent in 1300 (and only 10.1 percent in 1500), which

almost tripled in the subsequent 550 years to reach 24.5 percent in 1850, overtaking

average urbanization in the non-Atlantic parts of Western Europe between 1600 and

1700 (see also Table 1). Panels A and B in Figure 2 show the same pattern using

Maddison’s (2001) estimates of GDP per capita. While GDP per capita rose by a factor

of almost 2 among Atlantic traders between 1500 and 1820, in the rest ofWestern Europe

it grew at approximately the same rate as in Eastern Europe, just under 30 percent.

The patterns depicted in Figures 1 and 2 do not simply reflect the tendency of

more successful nations to engage in Atlantic trade. There is no differential growth of

Atlantic traders before the opening of Atlantic sea routes, and below we show similar

results using an exogenous measure of access to the Atlantic–ratio of Atlantic coastline

to land area–instead of the distinction between Atlantic traders and non-traders. Nor

do the results reflect some post-1500 advantage of coastal nations: Atlantic ports grew

much faster than other European cities, while Mediterranean ports grew at similar rates

to inland cities.

This evidence weighs against the most popular theories for the Rise of Europe, which

emphasize the continuity between pre-1500 and post-1500 growth and the importance

of certain distinctive European characteristics, such as culture, religion, geography or

features of the European state system.3 Instead, it is consistent with theories that

emphasize the importance of profits made in Atlantic trade, colonialism and slavery.4

2For the purposes of this paper, Western Europe is taken to be all the countries west of the Elbe,

i.e., Austria, Belgium, Britain, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands,

Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. Eastern Europe is all European countries to the

east of the Elbe, including Russia and excluding Turkey. See Section 1.1 for details on urbanization and

GDP data. All averages are weighted by population, using numbers from McEvedy and Jones (1978).

3See, e.g., Weber (1905), Jones (1981), Hall (1985), and Landes (1998).

4E.g., Williams (1944), Frank (1978), and Wallerstein (1974-1980).

2

Nevertheless, other evidence suggests that overseas trade and the associated profits

were not large enough to be directly responsible for the process of growth in Europe.

Engerman (1972) and O’Brien (1982) demonstrate that the contribution of profits from

slavery and trade with the rest of the world to European capital accumulation was

modest. O’Brien (1982, p. 2) writes that transoceanic trade “.... could in no way be

classified as decisive for economic growth of Western Europe”. Although recent work by

Inikori (2002) estimates larger trade flows than those of O’Brien, his estimates are not

large enough to suggest that European growth was driven solely by the direct impact of

Atlantic trade on profits or resources.

We advance the hypothesis that West European growth during this period resulted,

in part, from the indirect effects of international trade on institutional development.

Although there were some improvements in economic institutions in the late medieval

and early modern period, rapid economic development did not begin until the emergence

of political institutions providing secure property rights to a broader segment of society

and allowing free entry into profitable businesses (North and Thomas, 1973, and North

and Weingast, 1989). The critical political institutions were those that constrained the

power of the monarchy and allied groups.5 Checks on royal power and prerogatives

only emerged when groups that favored them, that is commercial interests outside the

royal circle, became sufficiently powerful politically. From 1500, and especially from

1600, onwards, in countries with non-absolutist initial institutions and easy access to

the Atlantic, the rise in Atlantic trade enriched and strengthened commercial interests

outside the royal circle, and enabled them to demand and obtain the institutional changes

necessary for economic growth. Although profits from Atlantic trade were small relative

to GDP, they were still substantial, and much larger than previous trading profits. For

example, Figure 3 shows that by the end of the 17th century, the volume of Atlantic

trade was much larger than that of long-distance Mediterranean trade (see the Appendix

for the construction of these series). The recipients of these profits became very rich

by the standards of the 17th- and 18th-century Europe, and typically politically and

socially very powerful.

These changes did not take place in countries with highly absolutist institutions,

such as, Spain, Portugal, and to a large extent France, where the crown was able to

closely control the expansion of trade. Consequently, in these countries, it was the

5It is important to note that these new political institutions neither protected the rights of all citizens

nor were democratic. They can best be characterized as oligarchic, since they increased the political

power of wealthy merchants, and at least in the British case, of the gentry and nascent industrial

interests. Nevertheless, they constituted a distinct improvement over the previous set of institutions,

which placed many fewer checks on the power of the monarchy.

3

monarchy and groups allied with it that were the main beneficiaries of the early profits

from Atlantic trade and plunder, and groups favoring changes in political institutions

did not become powerful enough to induce them. Our hypothesis therefore predicts

an important interaction between initial institutions and Atlantic trade, which is the

pattern we find in the data.

The major fact presented in this paper is consistent with the emphasis of a number

of historians, including, among others, Davis (1973a), de Vries (1984), Bairoch (1988),

Braudel (1992), and de Vries and van der Woude (1997). Although this historical literature

emphasizes the differential growth of Atlantic ports and Atlantic nations, to the

best of our knowledge, there are no other studies documenting the quantitative importance

of Atlantic traders and Atlantic ports or showing that the differential growth of

Western Europe is largely accounted for by the growth of Atlantic traders.

On the theoretical side, our hypothesis builds on the notion that institutional change,

even when socially beneficial, will be resisted by social groups who stand to lose economic

rents or political power. Consequently, the process of institutional change involves significant

conflict between different groups–in the European context, between the monarchy

and its allies versus commercial interests outside the royal circle.6 Our historical account

could also be viewed as a marriage between the Marxist thesis linking the rise of the

bourgeoisie and the development of the world economy (e.g., among others, Williams,

1944, Frank, 1978, and Wallerstein, 1974-1980) and the neoclassical emphasis on the

development of political institutions and secure property rights in Western Europe (e.g.,

North and Thomas, 1973, Jones, 1981, North, 1981, and De Long and Shleifer, 1993).

Distinct from these approaches, however, we offer an explanation based on the interaction

between Atlantic trade and medieval political institutions for why strong private

property rights emerged in Western Europe, especially in Britain and the Netherlands,

and starting in the 16th century. Although some scholars have noted the important

role of overseas merchants in particular instances of political change during this period

(most notably, Brenner, 2003 and Pincus, 2002, in the British case), we are not aware

of a theory along the lines developed in this paper.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 1 documents the key fact

of the paper, and shows that the pattern seen in Figure 1 and 2 is robust. Section 2

develops our hypothesis for the Rise of Europe and the role played by Atlantic trade in

6See, for example, North (1981), Olson (1982), Krusell and Rios-Rull (1996), Parente and Prescott

(1999), Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2002), and Rajan and Zingales (2003).

Rogowski (1989) is particularly notable in this context, since he also emphasizes how trade affects

political coalitions via its impact on factor prices, though he does not focus on how trade might induce

institutional change by strengthening commercial interests.

4

this process, and provides historical evidence supporting our interpretation. Sections 3

and 4 provide evidence on some implications of our hypothesis. Section 3 shows that

the evolution of European institutions is closely linked to Atlantic trade, and Section

4 documents an important interaction between initial institutions and Atlantic trade

in European economic growth. Section 5 concludes. The Appendix summarizes the

construction of the variables used in the empirical analysis, and further detail can be

found in Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, henceforth AJR, (2002b).

1 Atlantic Trade and the Rise of Europe

1.1 Data

We use three data series to measure economic development. First, we construct estimates

of urbanization based on the urban population numbers of Bairoch, Batou and

Ch`evre (1988). This is a comprehensive dataset with information on all 2,200 European

cities which had, at some time between 800 and 1800, 5,000 or more inhabitants.7 We use

these data as our measure of urban population and divide by the population estimates

of McEvedy and Jones (1978) to calculate urbanization (percent of the population living

in cities with more than 5,000 inhabitants). We also use estimates of urbanization rates

for Asia from the quantitative and qualitative assessments of Bairoch (1988). Bairoch

(1988, Ch. 1) and de Vries (1976, p. 164) argue that only areas with high agricultural

productivity and a developed transportation network could support large urban populations.

In addition, in AJR (2002a) we presented evidence that both in the time-series

and the cross-section there is a close association between urbanization and income per

capita before as well as after industrialization. We therefore take urbanization as a proxy

for GDP per capita.

Second, we use estimates of GDP per capita from Maddison (2001). These estimates

start in 1500, and are available for 1600, 1700, 1820, and then more frequently. Note

that these estimates are no more than educated guesses, especially before 1820. We

therefore think of these GDP data as a check on our results using urbanization data.

Third, we use the European city-level data from Bairoch, Batou and Ch`evre (1988),

to investigate which urban centers were driving demographic and economic growth, and

also to contrast the growth of Atlantic ports to other ports and to inland cities.

Table 1 gives the estimates of urbanization and income per capita at various dates.

7These data begin in 800, and there are estimates for every 100 years until 1700, then for every 50

years through 1850. However, Bairoch, Batou and Ch`evre (1988) emphasize that estimates before 1300

are rough and less reliable (and they skip the year 1100 due to lack of information). These data were

used previously by De Long and Shleifer (1993).

5

The first column is for the whole sample and is unweighted. The second column is

weighted by population in the corresponding year, giving a better sense of the aggregate

changes. The remaining columns give weighted means for Atlantic traders (Britain,

France, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain), forWest European countries that were not

Atlantic traders (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Norway,

Sweden and Switzerland), for East European countries, and for the Asian countries in

our sample.8 These numbers confirm the patterns shown in Figures 1 and 2. In the

regression analysis, we will report both weighted and unweighted results. The bottom

third of the table also shows the evolution of our measure of institutions, constraint on

the executive, which we will be described in greater detail and used in Section 3.

1.2 Economic Growth in Europe

Figures 1A and 1B above show the evolution of urbanization rates in Western and

Eastern Europe, and contrast the behavior of Atlantic traders vs. non-Atlantic traders.

We first look at Atlantic traders since the main beneficiaries from the Atlantic should

be those countries that engaged in Atlantic trade and colonialism. However, whether or

not a country is an Atlantic trader is clearly endogenous, i.e., it is the outcome of some

political or economic process. For this reason, we also present results using a measure

of access to the Atlantic, which is a country-level geographic characteristic.

We can test the idea that West European growth after 1500 was due primarily to

growth in countries involved in Atlantic trade or with a high potential for Atlantic trade

by estimating the following regression equation:

ujt = dt + δj + X t≥1600

αt · W Ej · dt + X t≥1500

βt · P ATj · dt + X0jt · γ + εjt, (1)

where ujt is urbanization in country j at time t, W Ej is a dummy indicating whether the

country is inWestern Europe, the dt’s denote year effects, the δj’s denote country effects,

Xjt is a vector of other covariates, and εjt is a disturbance term. In addition, P ATj ,

our measure of the potential for Atlantic trade, is a dummy for Atlantic trader (Britain,

France, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain) or alternatively, the Atlantic coastlineto-

area ratio (in both cases, a time-invariant characteristic of the country). The βt’s,

8We take current countries as the unit of observation. Although these do not always correspond

to the independent polities at the time, this discrepancy should not bias our empirical inference. For

example, if we had data on each Italian city-state, their average would show the same pattern as our

single Italy observation (presuming that our data for the aggregate of Italy are accurate), but because

of the larger number of observations, the standard errors would be smaller. The analysis of city-level

growth in Section 1.4 below is informative on differential growth across historical political boundaries.

6

the coefficients on the potential for Atlantic trade and the post-1500 time dummies, are

the main parameters of interest. Since our focus is on the rise of Western Europe as a

whole, our basic regressions are weighted by population in each year, but we also report

unweighted regressions for completeness.

Columns 1 and 2 of Table 2 only include the interaction terms between the Western

Europe dummy and dates from 1600, Pt≥1600 αt ·W Ej ·dt, which capture the differential

growth of West European countries relative to Eastern Europe. The top row reports the

p-value from the F-test of the joint significance of these interactions. Column 1 includes

data only for 1300-1850, while column 2 extends the sample back to 1000. Consistent

with Figure 1A, both specifications show significantly faster growth in Western Europe

than in Eastern Europe. For example, the point estimates (not shown in the table to

save space) indicate that in the specification of column 1, West European urbanization

grew by 6.9 percentage points relative to East European urbanization between 1500 and

1850.

Column 3 allows differential growth for countries engaged in Atlantic trade, by including

the term Pt≥1500 βt ·P ATj ·dt. We include 1500 as a “specification check” on the

timing of the effects. We start with P ATj as a dummy for Atlantic trader. Significant

positive estimates of βt’s imply that Atlantic traders grew starting in the period between

1500-1600. The estimates confirm the pattern seen in Figure 1B, and show large effects

from the interaction between the Atlantic trader dummy and dates after 1600. These

effects become statistically significant after 1750; in columns 8-10, the effects are statistically

significant starting in 1700. For example, the estimate for 1850, β1850 = 0.085,

implies that urbanization among Atlantic traders grew approximately by 8.5 percentage

points more than in other Western and Eastern European nations. Notice also that

the estimate of β1500 in this column, which measures the differential growth of Atlantic

traders between 1300-1400 and 1500, is insignificant and small. This is reassuring; since

Atlantic trade was very small before 1500, this finding shows that there is no differential

growth for Atlantic traders before Atlantic trade actually became important.9

Consistent with the patterns shown in Figure 1B, the inclusion of the Atlantic trade

interactions explains almost the entire differential growth of West European nations

9Although the above analysis does not count Denmark and Sweden as Atlantic traders, Sweden had

a small colony on the Delaware river 1637-1681 and Denmark controlled several small Caribbean islands

(now the U.S. Virgin Islands). To check the robustness of our results, we also experimented with a more

inclusive definition of Atlantic trader that includes Denmark and Sweden, with very similar to those

reported in column 3. The p-value for Western Europe x year interactions increases to [0.51], while

the pattern of coefficients on potential for Atlantic trade x year dummies is largely unchanged; the

interactions before 1700 are insignificant, then 0.035 (s.e.= 0.022) in 1700, 0.035 (s.e.= 0.021) in 1750,

0.046 (s.e.= 0.02) in 1800, and 0.08 (s.e.= 0.02) in 1850.

7

relative to Eastern Europe. The Pt≥1600 αt · W Ej · dt terms are no longer statistically

significant, and the point estimates (not shown in the table) imply that West European

urbanization grew only by 2.9 percentage points relative to Eastern Europe between

1300-1500 and 1850 as opposed to 6.9 percentage points in column 1.

Columns 4 and 5 show that the results are similar for the 1000-1850 period and when

observations are not weighted by population.10 Column 6 includes Asian countries. This

has little effect on the estimates of the differential growth of Atlantic traders, but now

West European countries are growing faster relative to the control group, which includes

Asian countries (see Figure 1A). Finally, Column 7 excludes Britain from the sample,

and shows that the results do not simply reflect British growth. The estimates in column

7 are about half the size of those in the other columns, but they show the same pattern.

An important concern with the results reported so far is endogeneity. Being Atlantic

trader is an ex post outcome, and perhaps only countries with high growth potential–

or those that were going to grow anyway–engaged in substantial Atlantic trade and

colonial activity. Belgium, Ireland, Denmark, Germany and Norway also had access to

the Atlantic, either directly or via the North Sea, but they did not take a major part

in long distance oceanic trade. In columns 8, 9 and 10, we use a geographic measure of

potential access to the Atlantic, Atlantic coastline-to-area ratio, as our time-invariant

P ATj variable, which gives positive Atlantic trade potential to all these countries.11 This

measure allows Atlantic trade to play a more important role in the growth of countries

with more Atlantic coastline relative to their land area.12

10In Column 4, the interaction between the West European dummy and the post-1500 dates is

significant at the 10 percent level, which reflects the lower level of East European urbanization in

the base period, which is now 1000-1400.

11Information on the length of coastline and the land area of particular countries is taken from Integrated

Coastline Management (on the web at http://icm.noaa.gov/country/ICM-pro.html), which

reports a standardized measure. We use only Atlantic coastline, i.e., omitting coastlines in the Mediterranean,

the Baltic and the Arctic. Details are provided in the Appendix of AJR (2002b). It is important

to exclude the Baltic coastlines of Denmark and Germany from our measure, since significant Baltic

trade predated the rise of Atlantic trade, and economic growth driven by Baltic trade could be an alternative

explanation for the patterns we observe. It any case, our results are generally robust to including

the Baltic or the Arctic coastlines. For example, we obtain very similar results to those reported in

Tables 2 and 3 when we include the west-facing coastline of Sweden, or when we include the entire

Norwegian coastline on the Arctic and the entire German coastline on the Baltic. Our results are also

generally similar when we include all the coastline of Sweden, Germany, Norway and the entire Baltic

coastline of Denmark, but the size of the coastline-to-area x year interactions are smaller than in our

baseline and Western Europe x year interactions become significant.

12Alternatively, we could use the Atlantic coastline-to-area measure as an instrument for the Atlantic

trader dummy. The results we report can be thought of as the reduced form for this IV strategy (a

univariate regression of the Atlantic trader dummy on the coastline-to-area measure in our sample has

an R2 of 0.30). Nevertheless, we prefer the specification in the text, since it is plausible that, even

conditional on being an Atlantic trader, a country with greater Atlantic coastline will trade and grow

more than another with less coastline, making such an IV procedure invalid. In fact, a comparison

8

The results using the coastline-to-area measure for P ATj are similar to those using

the Atlantic trader dummy. Most notably, the differential growth related to the Atlantic,

now captured by interactions with the Atlantic coastline-to-area ratio, is still strong; the

point estimates for the β’s are significant starting in 1700 and quantitatively large. For

example, the coefficient β1850 = 5.05 indicates approximately 6.5 percentage points more

urbanization growth in the Netherlands than in Italy between 1300-1400 and 1850 (the

Atlantic coastline-to-area ratio for the Netherlands is 0.013 and for Italy it is 0). This

explains over half of the differential 12 percentage point actual urbanization growth

between Italy and the Netherlands between these two dates. Other specifications using

the Atlantic coastline-to-area measure in columns 9 and 10 give similar results.

Equation (1) allows for an arbitrary pattern of differential growth in Atlantic traders.

Instead, we might expect the differential growth of Atlantic traders to be related to the

volume of Atlantic trade. For this reason, in Panel B we report results from estimating

a structured model of the form:

ujt = dt + δj + X t≥1600

αt · W Ej · dt + β · P ATj · ln ATt + X0jt · γ + εjt, (2)

where ATt denotes our estimate of the aggregate volume of Atlantic trade, shown in

Figure 3 above. The construction of this variable is explained briefly in the Appendix,

and further details and robustness results can be found in AJR (2002b).

Note that the model in equation (2) is more restrictive than that in (1), since we

are forcing the pattern of βt’s in (1) to be the same as that of ln ATt. In all columns,

the estimate of β, the coefficient on the interaction term between the log volume of

Atlantic trade and potential for Atlantic trade at the country level, is highly significant,

while the interaction terms between Western Europe and dates from 1600 onwards are

again insignificant. Notably, the R2 of this more restrictive regression is close to the

R2 of the flexible specifications reported in Panel A. These results suggest that the

significant interaction between potential for Atlantic trade and dates after 1600 is due

to the importance of Atlantic trade, not some other parallel process.

Table 3, which has the same structure as Table 2, provides regression evidence using

log GDP per capita as the dependent variable. Maddison (2001) reports estimates of

GDP per capita for 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820 and 1870. We take 1500 as the base year,

and add interactions between our measure of potential for Atlantic trade, P ATj, and

of columns 3-7 with columns 8-10 shows that the fit of the models with the Atlantic coastline-to-area

ratio is marginally better than those with the Atlantic trader dummy, because the former measure gives

greater potential for trade to Britain and the Netherlands, which have relatively high coastline-to-area

ratios.

9

the dates from 1600 on to capture the importance of Atlantic trade for the country (so

we can no longer test for pre-existing trends using the interaction between P ATj and

1500). Output numbers for 1870 are already heavily influenced by differential industrialization

experiences of various countries, so our baseline specification stops in 1820.

For completeness, we also report regressions that extend the sample to 1870.

Parallel to our results in Table 2, West European countries grow faster after 1500,

though this pattern is somewhat less pronounced, especially when we limit the sample to

1500-1820. The interactions between the Atlantic trader dummy and the dates after 1600

are typically significant starting either in 1600 or 1700, and quantitatively large. For

example, the estimate of β1820 = 0.27 in column 3 indicates that Atlantic traders grew,

on average, 31 percent (≈0.27 log points) more than non-Atlantic trader West European

nations between 1500 and 1820. Columns 4-7 report similar results to those in Table 2.

The pattern is the same when the sample is extended to 1870, with unweighted regressions,

when Britain is excluded from the sample, and when Asian countries are included.

Columns 8-10 report similar results using the Atlantic coastline-to-area measure.

Panel B of Table 3 reports structured models similar to (2) where we include the

interaction term, P ATj · ln ATt instead of the full set of post-1500 interactions between

P ATj and time dummies. This more structured specification again shows that the

differential growth of Western Europe from 1600 is closely linked to the extension of

Atlantic trader.

Overall both Table 2 and Table 3 show an important role for Atlantic trade in

West European growth. When the effect of Atlantic trade is not taken into account,

the estimates of αt’s are significant, positive and large–Western Europe is growing

faster than Eastern Europe and Asia. Once Atlantic trade interactions are included,

αt’s are typically no longer significant, while the effect of Atlantic trade is very strong.

Furthermore, the estimates show no evidence of differential growth by Atlantic traders

before the age of Atlantic trade.

1.3 Other Determinants of Economic Performance

To check the robustness of our results, Table 4 adds a number of covariates to our basic

regressions. The overall patterns are not affected. To save space, Table 4 only reports

the structured specifications of equation (2).

Weber (1905) and Landes (1998) argue that religion is an important determinant

of economic and social development. To assess the importance of religion, we allow

Protestant countries to grow at different rates than non-Protestant countries by inter-

10

acting a dummy for being a majority Protestant country in 1600 with year dummies

starting in 1600.13 The p-values from the joint significance test reported in columns 1 of

Panels A and C show that when the dependent variable is the urbanization rate, these

interactions are either insignificant or only marginally significant. In contrast, when

the dependent variable is log GDP per capita and we use the Atlantic trader dummy

for our potential Atlantic trade measure (Panel B), there is a significant effect from

these religion×year interactions. Nevertheless, this has little impact on the pattern of

differential growth between Western and Eastern Europe, or between Atlantic and non-

Atlantic trader. Moreover, the quantitative effects of Protestantism on economic growth

are smaller than those of Atlantic trade.14

Many social scientists view war-making as an important factor in the process of state

building and subsequent economic development (e.g., Hintze, 1970, Kennedy, 1987, Tilly,

1990). Incidence of wars might also proxy for the importance of inter-state competition,

which many historians, including Jones (1981) and Hall (1985), have emphasized. To

assess the importance of wars, in columns 2 and 6 we include a variable which is the

average number of years at war during the previous period (a century or half century).

We find that this variable itself is insignificant in the urbanization regressions and has

no effect on the patterns documented so far.15

A popular view sees the roots of European growth in the Roman Empire (e.g., Anderson,

1974, Jones 1981, Landes, 1998), and perhaps in the culture of Ancient Greece.

To investigate whether Roman heritage is important for the Rise of Europe, we created

a dummy that indicates whether a country was part of the Roman Empire. We then

interacted this variable with dates from 1600 onwards to see whether there is differential

growth depending on the extent of Roman heritage (columns 3 and 7). These interactions

are typically insignificant, and do not affect the patterns reported in the previous

tables. The only exception is when we use log GDP per capita as the dependent variable

and the Atlantic trader dummy for P ATj . But in this case, the results indicate

13See the Appendix for the construction of the variables used in this subsection.

14The point estimates (not reported) imply that Protestant countries experienced 4.5 percentage

points greater urbanization growth between 1500 and 1850, and 30 percent more GDP growth between

1500 and 1820. The corresponding numbers for Atlantic traders in the flexible specifications including

the Protestant dummy interacted with dates from 1600 are 8.4 percentage points more urbanization

and 41 percent more GDP growth.

15As an alternative exercise more favorable to the war hypothesis, we also controlled for the average

number of years at war that ended in victory during the previous 50 or 100 years. To the extent that

rich nations are more likely to succeed in war, the coefficient on this variable will be biased upwards.

The inclusion of this variable has remarkably little effect on our estimates of the interaction between

access to the Atlantic (or Atlantic trader) and the post-1500 years (or the volume of Atlantic trade),

and this war variable itself is insignificant when the dependent variable is the urbanization rate and

marginally significant with log GDP per capita.

11

that countries with Roman heritage grew more rapidly between 1400 and 1600, and

significantly slower thereafter.

Finally, in columns 4 and 8 we add interactions between distance from the equator

(the absolute value of the latitude of the nation’s capital) and dates from 1600 to see

whether the move of economic activity away from Southern towards Northern Europe

can explain the rise of Atlantic nations. Once again the addition of these variables does

not affect the importance of Atlantic trade, and the latitude interactions are typically

insignificant (except in Panel B where the point estimates have the wrong sign).

1.4 Urban Expansion and Atlantic Ports

We next turn to an analysis of data on the population of individual cities compiled

by Bairoch, Batou and Ch`evre (1988). Figure 4A shows that the urban expansion of

Western Europe was driven by cities that were Atlantic ports. Table 5 confirms this

pattern with regression analysis. It estimates models similar to (1), with the log of

city-level urban population as the dependent variable. The key right-hand side variable

is the interaction between a dummy indicating whether the city is an Atlantic port (or

in our alternative specification, whether it is a potential Atlantic port), denoted by APi,

and dummies from 1500.16 The sample for all regressions in Table 5 is the balanced

panel of cities for which we have observations in each date.17

In column 1, APi is a dummy for Atlantic port, and observations are weighted by

current population in each year. The interactions between the Atlantic port dummy

and dates after 1600, the APi · dt terms, are statistically and economically significant

and positive. For example, the coefficient of 0.79 implies that Atlantic ports grew approximately

120 percent (≈0.79 log points) relative to other cities between 1300-1400

and 1800. Notably, there appears to be no differential growth of Atlantic ports before

1600, once again supporting the notion that the growth of these ports is related to the

emergence of trading and colonial opportunities via the Atlantic. In the bottom panel,

16See the Appendix of AJR (2002b) for the list of Atlantic ports in our panel. In Figures 4 and 5,

we use the definition of actual Atlantic port. In the regression analysis, we also report results with a

dummy for potential Atlantic port. The distinction between Atlantic port and potential Atlantic port

parallels our use of Atlantic trader dummy and the coastline-to-area measure of potential for Atlantic

trade in Tables 2, 3 and 4.

17The focus on a balanced panel of cities avoids problems of composition bias, which would result

from the fact that cities enter the data set only once they exceed a certain threshold (typically 5,000

people). For example, if an area is growing rapidly, the population of the smaller cities in this area will

also grow and exceed the relevant threshold, but the addition of cities with population around 5,000

may reduce the average population of the cities in this area. Nevertheless, in practice this bias does not

seem to be important, and in AJR (2002b) we report similar results using a larger, unbalanced panel

of cities.

12

we report results from a structured specification similar to equation (2). Once again,

the coefficient on the interaction term between the volume of Atlantic trade and the

Atlantic port dummy is highly significant, and the R2 of this more restrictive regression

is almost the same as the regression reported in the top panel.

Column 2 reports estimates from an unweighted regression. The results are similar,

but quantitatively smaller, since large Atlantic ports, such as London and Amsterdam,

no longer get more weight. Columns 3 and 4 report weighted and unweighted estimates

from similar models, with a dummy for potential Atlantic port– that is, any city that in

our balanced panel that could have been used as a port for Atlantic trade. The results

are similar to those in columns 1 and 2.18 Column 5 drops London and Amsterdam

to show that the results are not driven by these two major cities. The coefficients on

Atlantic port times year interactions are approximately halved from 1700 onwards, but

they remain significant. Column 6 adds a full set of country times year interactions

to show the differential growth of Atlantic ports relative to other cities in the same

country. The coefficients on Atlantic port times year interactions after 1700 are about

half those of column 1, but still highly statistically significant. Column 7 adds Asian

cities from Chandler (1987), so now West European cities are being compared to both

East European and Asian cities. The results are similar, but also show the differential

growth of all West European cities relative to Asian cities.19

Is there something special about ports, or is it Atlantic ports that are behaving

differently after 1500? To answer this question, Figure 4B and column 8 show that

Mediterranean ports grew at similar rates to inland European cities; what we find is not

a general port effect but an Atlantic port effect.

Was the urban and economic expansion of Atlantic nations driven solely by the

growth of Atlantic ports? Figure 5A shows the expansion of Iberian (Spanish and Portuguese)

Atlantic ports, other Iberian cities, and West European inland cities. Almost

all of the differential growth of Spain and Portugal comes from Atlantic ports. In fact,

non-Atlantic parts of Spain and Portugal grew slower than West European inland cities.

Relevant to our hypothesis below, this Iberian pattern contrasts with the steady growth

18To allow for the specification test discussed in the text, these regressions use 1300-1400 as the base

period. Because there was rapid growth in a few potential–but not actual–Atlantic ports from 1400 to

1500, some of the coefficients on potential Atlantic port are higher than the corresponding coefficients

on Atlantic port. However, cumulative growth between 1500 and any subsequent date is always higher

for Atlantic ports than for potential Atlantic ports. It should also be noted that some potential Atlantic

ports flourished as a result of secondary trade from the Atlantic.

19We also investigated the importance of the same controls used in Table 4 for country-level growth.

The results, which are reported in AJR (2002b), show that the pattern in Table 5 is robust to the

inclusion of these controls.

13

of non-Atlantic British cities shown in Figure 5B (notice that the non-Atlantic British

line starts below the West European line and overtakes it by 1850, see AJR 2002b for

further evidence).

1.5 Interpretation

The evidence presented so far has established a significant relationship between the

potential for Atlantic trade and post-1500 economic development, and suggests that the

opportunities to trade through the Atlantic, and the associated profits from colonialism

and slavery, played an important role in the Rise of Europe. This evidence weighs

against theories linking the Rise of Western Europe to the continuation of pre-1500

trends driven by certain distinctive characteristics of European nations or cultures, such

as Roman heritage or religion.

At face value, this evidence is more consistent with theories emphasizing the direct

contribution of profits from Atlantic trade, colonialism and slavery, such as those

advanced by Williams (1944), Frank (1978), and Wallerstein (1974-1980). It is undoubtedly

true that colonial relations with the New World and Asia contributed to European

growth. Nevertheless, quantitative analyses, for example, Engerman (1972), Engerman

and O’Brien (1981), O’Brien (1982), and Bairoch (1995, chapter 5), suggest that the

volume of trade and the profits generated by Atlantic trade appear to be too small to

account for much of European growth directly. Atlantic trade may have also played

an important direct role by inducing a reallocation of resources within Europe, even if

profits from trading were low (as would be the case in a competitive economy). This

direct channel is unlikely to be the whole story either, since the volume of trade was

small. For example, Bairoch (1995) calculates that commodity trade between Western

Europe and the rest of the world amounted to less than 4 percent of the GNP of Western

Europe before 1800. Although recent work by Inikori (2002) argues that profits from

colonial activities, in particular from the slave trade, were larger than those estimated

by O’Brien, even with his estimates, the direct effect of Atlantic trade and colonialism

could account for the Rise of Europe only with significant increasing returns to scale in

leading sectors.20

20For example, O’Brien (1982) calculates that total profits from British trade with less developed

regions of the world during the late 18th century were approximately $5.6 million, while total gross

investment during the same period stood at $10.3 million. Inikori (2002, Table 4.2) suggests that

imports from the periphery around 1800 were about double O’Brien’s estimate. During this period, the

aggregate savings rate was between 12 and 14 percent, so if we assume that this savings rate also applies

to profits from trade, the contribution of these profits to aggregate capital accumulation would be less

than 15 percent, even using Inikori’s estimates. Even assuming considerably higher savings rates, the

14

Overall, therefore, the weight of evidence inclines us towards a view in which the

Rise of Europe reflects not only the direct effects of Atlantic trade and colonialism, but

also a major social transformation induced by these opportunities.

2 OurHypothesis

2.1 The Argument

Our hypothesis is that Atlantic trade–the opening of the sea routes to the New World,

Africa, and Asia and the building of colonial empires–contributed to the process ofWest

European growth between 1500 and 1850 not only through its direct economic effects,

but also indirectly by inducing fundamental institutional changes. Atlantic trade in

Britain and the Netherlands (or more appropriately, in England and the Duchy of Burgundy)

altered the balance of political power by enriching and strengthening commercial

interests outside the royal circle, including various overseas merchants, slave traders and

various colonial planters. Through this channel, it contributed to the emergence of political

institutions protecting merchants against royal power.21 Our hypothesis also implies

that the tendency for institutional change to emerge should have been much stronger in

societies with already-existing checks on royal power than in countries with absolutist

regimes and monarchy-controlled trade monopolies, because in these latter countries

Atlantic trade did not enrich and strengthen merchant groups outside the royal circle as

much, and did not disturb the political status quo.

This hypothesis can be broken into 4 subhypotheses:

1. Political institutions placing limits and constraints on state power are essential

for the incentives to undertake investments and for sustained economic growth.

2. In early modern Europe, such political institutions were favored by commercial

interests outside the royal circle, but were not welcome by the monarchy and its allies.

3. Institutions favored by economically and politically powerful groups are more

likely to prevail.

4. In countries with non-absolutist initial political institutions, Atlantic trade and

colonial activity enriched and strengthened commercial interests, including new groups

without ties to the monarchy.

Together these four subhypotheses yield our main hypothesis. In countries with easy

contribution would remain relatively small.

21An additional channel via which Atlantic trade may have contributed to institutional change may

be the desire of the monarchy to secure the property rights of merchants in order to encourage longterm

investments in long distance trade. Our reading of the relevant history, discussed below, makes us

believe that the greater contribution of Atlantic trade to the development of capitalist institutions was

by strengthening commercial interests in favor of political change in their fight against the monarchy.

15

access to the Atlantic and without a strong absolutist monarchy, Atlantic trade provided

substantial profits and political power for commercial interests outside the royal circle.

This group could then demand and obtain significant institutional reforms protecting

their property rights. With their newly gained power and property rights, they took

advantage of the growth opportunities offered by Atlantic trade, invested more, traded

more, and fueled the First Great Divergence.22

Initial institutions placing sufficient checks on the monarchy are essential for the

fourth subhypothesis, so that merchants not directly associated with the crown benefit

significantly from Atlantic trade. When the power of the crown was relatively unchecked,

as in Spain, Portugal and France, trade was largely monopolized and regulated, the crown

and its allies became the main beneficiaries of the Atlantic expansion, and the same

induced institutional changes did not take place. Therefore, our hypothesis explains not

only the major role played by Atlantic trade in West European growth, but also why

economic growth took off in Britain and the Netherlands, and not in Spain and Portugal.

AJR (2002b) provided historical evidence consistent with these subhypotheses. Space

constraints preclude us from going into details here. We refer the reader to that paper

for a more detailed discussion, and briefly discuss the evidence related to the fourth

subhypothesis, which is perhaps the most important for our argument.

2.2 Atlantic Trade and Commercial Interests

We now discuss the major changes in the political institutions of Britain and the Netherlands.

Our argument highlights that in both cases: (1) the political institutions at the

beginning of the 16th century, though not as absolutist as in Spain and Portugal, did

not provide secure property rights to commercial interests outside the royal circle;23 (2)

there was significant conflict between these merchant groups and the monarchy; (3) Atlantic

trade created large profits for some of these merchants in favor of institutional

change, who then used part of these profits to support the conflict against the crown.

Britain. In the British case the two milestones in the emergence of political institutions

constraining royal power are the (English) Civil War of 1642-49, when Parliamentarian

forces defeated Charles I, and the Glorious Revolution of 1688—89, where

James II was deposed by the Parliament with the help of an invading Dutch army, and

22The establishment of political institutions limiting the power of the monarchy may have also created

positive spillovers on the rest of the economy, especially on industrial capitalists (consistent with the

subsequent growth of non-Atlantic British cities in Figure 5B).

23More explicitly, these commercial interests included merchants not receiving crown-granted monopolies,

slave traders, various producers in the colonies and parts of the gentry in Britain, and the

majority of the Dutch merchants not allied with the Habsburg monarchy in the Netherlands.

16

replaced by William of Orange and a parliamentary regime with a constitutional monarchy.

Although there is no consensus among historians on the relative importance of

these two events, this is secondary for our focus. What is important is that there was

a major improvement in British political institutions between the mid 17th and early

18th centuries.

Although after the War of the Roses, Britain was never as absolutist as France,

Portugal and Spain, both the Tudor and Stuart monarchs consistently attempted to

expand their powers. The insecurity of property rights was clear during the reign of

Henry VIII, when there were continual attempts to regulate trade and undermine the

powers of the Parliament (see Elton, 1991). A significant attempt to establish a form

of absolutism came during the period of so-called “personal rule” of Charles I, after he

dissolved his third parliament in 1629, raised taxes in an unconstitutional way, and used

the Star Chamber to manipulate legal decisions in his favor (Sharpe, 1992).

Though undoubtedly complex social events, both the Civil War and the Glorious

Revolution were also battles over the rights and prerogatives of the monarchy.24 In both

cases, commercial interests (including large segments, but not all, of the merchants and

the gentry) predominantly sided with those demanding restrictions on the power of the

monarchy. During the Civil War, for example, the majority of the merchants, and even

many of those with royal monopolies, supported the Parliament (see Brenner, 1973, 2003,

Keeler, 1954, and Brunton and Pennington, 1954).25 Members of the Commons from

the City of London, which was the main center of mercantile activity, as well as many

non-London commercial constituencies, such as Southampton, Newcastle and Liverpool,

supported the Parliament against the King. Sacks (1991, pp. 230-247) shows that in

Bristol trading, commercial and industrial interests outside of theMerchant Adventurers,

the trading company then enjoying the royal monopoly, were Parliamentarians. Brunton

24Other prominent interpretations of the English Civil War have emphasized various factors apart

from those we stress here. Russell (1990) argues that the Civil War was a plot by the traditional

aristocracy to regain power it had lost under the Tudors. Many, for example, Morrill (1993), focus on

the role of religious differences in determining who supported which side, and recent work by Manning

(1996) stresses more general class conflict. Although there are doubtless elements of truth in these

approaches, the general role of mercantile interests seems undeniable (see Richardson, 1998, for a

balanced overview of the debate).

25Pearl’s seminal study (1961) argued that there were political divisions between groups such as the

Merchant Adventurers who benefited from monopolies granted by the crown and new merchants, who

did not. For example, the two pre-Civil War MPs for Bristol, Humphrey Hooke and Richard Long

were Royalists. Ashton (1979, 1996), on the other hand, documented that even merchants who enjoyed

monopolies tended to oppose the crown by the Civil War, and argued “the majority of the City fathers,

far from being the natural supporters of Stuart absolutism at the end of the period of Charles I’s

personal rule in the late 1630’s, were as alienated from royal policies as were the vast majority of the

political nation” (1996, p. 3).

17

and Pennington (1954, p. 62) also note that “in the country as a whole there was

probably a preponderance of Parliamentarian feeling among merchants.”

The situation for the Glorious Revolution is similar. The East India Company under

the control of Josiah Child supported James II, his claim to tax without consent of

Parliament, and his right to grant trading monopolies–of which it was the main benefi-

ciary. But the majority of commercial interests, alienated by James II’s grants of various

monopoly privileges, and especially the interlopers–merchants trying to break into trade

with Asia–were on the side of the revolution (Carruthers, 1996, Pincus, 2002). These

merchants also received strong support from Whigs who sought to constrain the king

(Horwitz, 1978). Summarizing the evidence, Pincus (2002, p. 34) concludes “England’s

merchant community actively supported William’s plan for invasion, and provided a key

financial prop to the regime in the critical early months.”

The victory of Parliament in the Civil War and after the Glorious Revolution introduced

major checks on royal power and strengthened the rights of merchants. After the

Civil War, the fraction of MPs who were merchants increased dramatically. Although,

even in the 1690s, this number was not large enough to constitute a majority on its

own, as Stasavage (2003) shows, the interests of merchants were assured by the formation

of the Whig coalition of merchants and Protestant landowners. This period also

witnessed a series of policies favoring merchants, including the Navigation Acts of 1651

and 1660, which restricted trade with British colonies to British ships and merchants

(Farnell, 1964, Cooper, 1972) and strengthened the position of British overseas traders

(especially slave traders, see Holmes, 1993, p. 64). Similarly, the Glorious Revolution led

to a series of economic reforms sought by merchants outside the royal circle, including

the dismantling of all monopoly charters, except the East India Company (Gauci, 2001),

and the establishment of the Bank of England. The conventional wisdom in economic

history emphasizes the importance of these institutional changes for the protection of

property rights, and how they led to a wave of innovations in economic institutions, particularly

in financial markets (e.g., North and Weingast, 1989, Carruthers, 1996, Neal,

2000).

Critically for our thesis, the major changes in political institutions and the new

assertiveness of merchant groups coincided with the expansion of British mercantile

groups trading through the Atlantic. The East India Company was founded in 1600,

and from 1600 to 1630 there was an unprecedented wave of investment by merchants,

gentry, and even some aristocracy in overseas ventures (Rabb, 1967). Virginia tobacco

cultivation boomed in the 1620s and from the 1640s the highly profitable Caribbean

18

sugar colonies started to develop. Finally, in the 1650s the British began to take over

the Atlantic slave trade.

A number of historians, most notably Brenner (2003), have emphasized that Atlantic

merchants were critical in ensuring the military victory of Parliament in the Civil War.

In his famous book Stone also points out that: “... other important merchant elements

can now be identified, men interested especially in the American trades, in New England

colonization, and in breaking the monopoly of the East India and Levant Companies.

They were new men in new fields of entrepreneurial endeavor who chafed at the political

and economic stranglehold of the older established monopolistic oligarchies. These men

were important members of the group of radicals who seized control of London at a

critical moment in 1641, and so swung the power and influence of the city decisively on

the side of Parliament” (1972, p. 144).

Atlantic trade indeed created large profits for the fortunate who succeeded in this

high-risk endeavor. In the Appendix, we use data on profits from Chaudhuri (1965)

and de Vries and van der Woude (1997), on investment from Rabb (1967), on trade

from Inikori (2002) and de Vries (2001), and on rates of return from Grassby (1969

and 1970) and O’Brien (1982) to estimate profits of various merchant companies, slave

traders and colonial planters from Atlantic trade during this period. These estimates

suggest that profits from Atlantic trade were negligible before 1575, about $40,000

on average per annum from 1576-1600 (mostly from a few highly profitable privateering

expeditions), perhaps $200,000 on average per annum from 1601-1650, around $500,000

p.a. from 1651-1675, and then rose with the expansion of sugar and the slave trade to

around $900,000 p.a. in 1676-1700, $1.7m p.a. in 1701-1750, and probably about $5m

p.a. in the late 18th century (all figures adjusted to 1600 prices using the index of

building craftsmen’s wages from Phelps-Brown and Hopkins, 1955). These profits were

substantial relative to the personal wealth of merchants and gentry during this time

period. For example, personal wealth of $ 10,000 in the early 17th century was enough

to be very rich. A minimum investment of $2,000 was required to become a director

of the East India Company, and $200 represented a substantial investment (Brenner,

1973, pp. 62-63; Brenner, 2003, p. 78). Moreover, because profits from Atlantic trade

were highly concentrated, they created a number of very wealthy merchants (see Grassby,

1995, p. 248 and p. 263). These profits were also large relative to the resources necessary

to make a difference politically and militarily.26

26The English monarch was always short of cash from 1550 to 1688, and war typically required

additional funds. For example, King Charles I was forced to recall Parliament in 1640 because he

needed to raise about $ 300,000 ($250,000 in 1600 prices) for war against Scotland–enough to pay and

19

Many merchants used their profits from Atlantic trade to support the conflict against

the crown. For example, the Earl of Warwick, who earned at least $50,000 from privateering

in one year prior to the Civil War (Craven, 1930), applied his fortune and

experience with naval warfare to effectively oppose the king.27 More generally, Parliament

during the Civil War was partly financed by taxes on and profits from Atlantic

trade. Parliamentary leaders such as Sir Edwin Sandys and John Pym were active in

colonization and trade with the Americas. James I, well aware of the links between major

Atlantic trading ventures and Parliamentary opposition, intervened in the election

of treasurer for the Virginia Company, saying “Choose the devil if you will, but not Sir

Edwin Sandys” (Rabb, 1998, p. 349). Similarly, for the Glorious Revolution, Pincus

(2002, pp. 32-33) provides evidence that “the merchant community poured money into

William of Orange’s coffers in 1688”– perhaps around $ 800,000 (about $500,000 in

1600 prices), enough to pay for a sizable army.

The Netherlands. Dutch merchants always had considerable autonomy and access

to profitable trade opportunities. Nevertheless, prior to the Dutch Revolt, the Netherlands

(in fact, the entire Duchy of Burgundy) was part of the Habsburg Empire, and the

political power of Dutch merchants was limited. The Habsburg monarchy consistently

attempted to increase its political dominance over and fiscal revenues from the Netherlands

(Fritschy, ’t Hart, and Horlings, 2001). The critical improvement in Dutch political

institutions was therefore the establishment of the independent Dutch Republic, with

political dominance and economic security for merchants, including both the established

wealthy Regents and the new merchants immigrating from Antwerp and Germany.28

Dutch politics was shaped by the conflict between Dutch merchants and the Habsburg

monarchy starting in the 15th century, and before then by the conflict between merchants

and the Duke of Burgundy. By 1493 Maximilian of Habsburg had reversed the Grand

Privilege of 1477, which gave the States General the right to gather on their own initiative

equip about 12,000 soldiers for a year (Ashton, 1960, p.176). Total English government revenues were

around $500,000 in 1600 and about $850,000 in 1640 (Bean, 1973). Armies on both sides of the English

Civil War were small, 10,000-20,000 men, and most of the conflict was small-scale local operations by

regional forces (Parker, 1988, p. 28 and p. 41). Parliament fielded 27,000 at the battle of Marston

Moor and just 13,000 at Naseby; the presence or absence of a few thousand troops was therefore decisive

(Parker, 1988, p. 41). Kennedy (1987 p. 63) estimates that the average annual cost of a soldier was

around $27 in 1657 (about $20 in 1600 prices).

27A privateer is an armed private vessel bearing the authorization or commission of a sovereign power

to attack an enemy, i.e., a privately funded and manned extension of a country’s naval forces. Privateers

typically engaged in trading activities as well as fighting (see, for example, the case of John Hawkins

discussed in Rodger, 1997, p. 201).

28By 1600 a third of the population of Amsterdam were immigrants (Israel, 1995, p. 309). In 1631

there were 685 citizens of Amsterdam with wealth over 25,000 florins. Only half of them were native

Hollanders (Parker, 1977, p. 251).

20

and curbed the right of the ruler to raise taxes. After 1552, war with France and England

increased the Habsburgs’ fiscal needs and led them to impose a large tax burden on the

Netherlands. Growing fiscal and religious resentment in 1572 led to a series of uprisings,

mostly orchestrated by commercial interests (see Israel, 1995). These culminated in a

war of independence, which began with the Revolt in the 1570s and did not end until

1648, punctuated by Philip II diverting resources to intervene in France after 1590, the

successful Dutch offensives of 1591-97 under the command of Maurice of Nassau, the

embargoes against Dutch trade with Spain and Portugal in 1585-90, 1598-1609, 1621-47,

and the Twelve Years truce from 1609 to 1621.

The major turning point came in the 1590s when important changes in Dutch military

and commercial strategy became evident. New military tactics made it possible for the

Dutch to hold their own against experienced Spanish infantry (Parker, 1988, pp. 19-

20). This was combined with a fiscal and financial “revolution” that allowed states,

particularly Holland, to both increase their tax revenues and borrow against future

taxes in order to finance the war effort (Fritschy, 2003). At the same time, the Dutch

took the critical strategic step of seeking direct access to Asian and American trade

centers. This both enriched a generation of Dutch merchants and undermined Spanish

and Portuguese revenues sufficiently to induce Philip III to offer peace. By 1605 it

was clear to a Spanish royal councillor, the Count of Olivares, that victory would go to

“whoever is left with the last escudo” (Parker, 1977, p. 238).

Merchants were naturally the primary political and economic force on the side of

independence. De Vries and van der Woude (1997) argue that “urban economic interests

ultimately believed it advantageous to escape the Habsburg imperial framework”

(p. 369). They also note that, in the case of Amsterdam, the “[Habsburgs’] opponents

included most of the city’s international merchants....[I]n 1578 a new Amsterdam city

council threw the city’s lot in with the Prince of Orange... among the merchants returning

from... exile were [those whose families] and several generations of their descendents

would long dominate the city” (1997, p. 365).

Commercial interests involved in the Atlantic were particularly important in the

shaping of the conflict (see for example, Israel, 1982, 1995, and van der Wee, 1993,

pp. 272-273). In 1609, in an attempt to prevent the creation of the Dutch West India

Company, Philip III offered peace and independence in return for a Dutch withdrawal

from both the West and East Indies. But these terms were “simply not feasible politically

because many regents and elite merchants had invested heavily in the [Dutch

East India Company]” (Israel, 1995, p. 402). Prominent in the anti-peace camp was

21

the famous Dutch leader and general Maurice of Nassau, who was heavily involved in

colonial trades, and “Reynier Pauw, the pre-eminent figure and leader of the anti-truce

faction in Holland, besides being a champion of the West India Company project, had

been a founder member of the East India Company and for many years a director of its

Amsterdam chamber.” (Israel, 1982, p. 40).

It is therefore no surprise that independence put merchants firmly in control of the

political process. De Vries and van der Woude (1997, p. 587) describe the new political

elite following the Dutch Revolt as: “6 to 8% of urban households with incomes in

excess of 1,000 guilders per year. This was the grote burgerij from whom was drawn the

political and commercial leadership of the country. Here we find, first and foremost, the

merchants.” They also point out how merchants dominated the governments of Leiden,

Rotterdam and the cities in two largest states, Zeeland and Holland.

The Dutch economy had been expanding since the 15th century, and experienced

advances in economic institutions, including in shipping, agriculture and finance, particularly

public finance, prior to this revolt (Tracy 1985, van Zanden 1993). Nevertheless,

the potential of these institutions were severely limited under the Habsburg yoke because

of the threat of arbitrary taxation. For example, ’t Hart, Jonker and van Zanden

(1997, Figure 2.3, p. 19) show that, despite the changes in financial institutions in

the mid-16th century, interest rates did not fall systematically until after 1600 when

they declined to about 1/3 of their pre-revolt level. Consequently, the economy appears

to have experienced a major transformation after the process of political change

began. Van Zanden (1993) notes that: “we can see the starting point of the rapid urbanization

at 1580” (pp. 35-36) and continues: “during this transformation process,

the pre-1580 proto-capitalist structure disappeared . . . out of this ‘unspecialised’ class

of small-holders, fishermen, homeworkers and sailors, separate classes of large farmers,

agricultural laborers and craftsmen arose” (p. 39). Similarly, Braudel (1995, p. 547)

dates the start of the divergence between the South and North of Europe to 1590 with

the “explosion” of Dutch commerce and the rise of Amsterdam.

Critical was the Dutch merchants’ improving economic fortunes, partly from Atlantic

trade, which were used to field a powerful army against the Habsburg Empire. The Baltic

trade is widely recognized as important for the Dutch economy in the 16th century, but

profits from Atlantic trade quickly surpassed those from Baltic trade, and provided the

funds necessary for the Dutch military effort against the Habsburgs (Israel, 1989). De

Vries and van der Woude (1997) estimate that the annual profits of the Dutch East India

Company alone between 1630 and 1670, 2.1 million guilders per annum, were more than

22

twice the total annual profits from the Baltic grain trade between 1590 and 1599 (pp.

373 and 447).

Fritschy (2003) estimates that, as a result of these developments, tax revenue per

head in Holland rose nearly 5 times from 1575 to 1610, while population increased by

a third (see also Tracy, 2001, Table 7.2). These revenues enabled Holland to provide

960,000 guilders for the war in 1579 and to pay 5m guilders in 1599 (Parker, 1977, p.

251). Israel (1995, pp. 241-242) summarizes the basic reason for the Dutch victory

as follows: “From 1590, there was a dramatic improvement in the Republic’s economic

circumstances. Commerce and shipping expanded enormously, as did the towns. As a

result, the financial power of the states rapidly grew, and it was possible to improve the

army vastly, both qualitatively, and quantitatively, within a short space of time. The

army increased from 20,000 men in 1588 to 32,000 by 1595, and its artillery, methods of

transportation, and training were transformed.” By 1629, the Dutch were able to field

an army of 77,000 men, 50% larger than the Spanish army of Flanders (Israel, 1995, p.

507).

Overall, both the British and Dutch evidence therefore appears favorable to our

hypothesis that Atlantic trade enriched a group of merchants who then played a critical

role in the emergence of new political institutions constraining the power of the crown.

Spain, Portugal and France. There is general agreement that Spanish and Portuguese

political institutions at the turn of the 16th century were more absolutist than those in

Britain and the Netherlands, and did not experience similar improvements.29

A key difference between these cases and the British-Dutch patterns is the organization

of trade, which, in turn, reflected differences in political institutions. Throughout

this period, the granting of trade monopolies was a central tool for the rulers to raise

revenue. When the power of the monarchs was constrained, they were unable to use this

fiscal tool. For example, the English Parliament successfully blocked many attempts of

both Tudor and Stuart monarchs to create such monopolies (Hill, 1969). Consequently,

in Britain “most trade was carried on by individuals and small partnerships, and not by

29Davis (1973b, p. 66), for example, emphasizes the high degree of absolute control by the monarchy

in Spain as follows: [in Castille] “the king ruled subject only to weak constitutional restraints. In the

first decades of the sixteenth century the crown had reduced the pretensions of the Castillian nobility

and towns, so that the representative body, the Cortes, could obstruct but not in the last resort prevent

royal tax raising,” and contrasts this with the situation in Britain (e.g., Davis, 1973b, p. 210).

The modern literature, in particular, Thompson (1994) and Graves (2001), suggests that the extent of

Spanish absolutism has been overemphasized by scholars such as North and Thomas (1973), and points

out important differences between Castille and other parts of Iberia such as Aragon and Catalonia.

Nevertheless, it is certainly true that the Spanish Crown was able to create trade monopolies and raise

taxes in ways that the Tudor and Stuart monarchies could not.

23

the Company of Merchant Adventurers, the Levant Company ... or others of their kind”

(Davis, 1973b, p. 41). At least by 1600 there was quite free entry into the British merchant

class (Lang, 1974). In contrast, Cameron (1993, p. 127) describes the Portuguese

situation as follows: “The spice trade in the East Indies of the Portuguese Empire was a

crown monopoly; the Portuguese navy doubled as a merchant fleet, and all spices had to

be sold through the Casa da India (India House) in Lisbon ... no commerce existed between

Portugal and the East except that organized and controlled by the state” (see also

Boxer, 1985, and Hamilton, 1948). Similarly, in Spain colonial trade was a monopoly of

the Crown of Castille and was delegated to the Casa de Contrataci´on (House of Trade)

in Seville, which was itself closely monitored by the government (Parry, 1966, Ch 2).

France, on the other hand, can be viewed as an intermediate case. Although French

institutions were equally absolutist (Church, 1969, Parrott, 2001), early Atlantic activity

enriched some merchant groups, in particular, the protestant Huguenots. However, the

monarchy soon clashed with and defeated the Huguenots, first with the siege of La

Rochelle by Louis XIII and then the outlawing of the Protestant church by Louis XIV

(see, e.g., Scoville, 1960). The monarchy then kept much of overseas trading activity

as a royal monopoly, especially under Colbert (see, e.g., Davis, 1973a, pp. 222-224,

and Doyle, 1974, pp. 210-211). Nevertheless, certain strong French commercial and

industrial interests developed, and arguably, forced institutional change before, during

and after the French Revolution (see Lefebvre, 1947, and Doyle, 1988, for the debate on

the origins of the French Revolution).

Overall, the evidence is therefore consistent with our thesis that in Spain and Portugal,

and also largely in France, merchant interests with sufficient power to challenge

the crown did not develop because the crown, and groups allied to it, were the main

beneficiaries of the profits from transoceanic trade and plunder.

3 Atlantic Trade and Institutional Change

We now attempt to substantiate our hypothesis further by providing empirical evidence

on the link between changes in political institutions and Atlantic trade. A prerequisite

for this exercise is a measure of relevant political institutions. Unfortunately, no such

measure exists for this period.30 So as a first step, we attempted to create a measure

of political institutions for European countries between 1300 and 1850, adapting the

30An alternative approach would be to use the terms of finance for trading entities, as suggested by

one of our reviewers. Although there are some data on this, the coverage is not broad enough for our

purposes. Moreover, the terms of finance may be affected by the demand for and supply of financial

resources as well as the underlying security of property rights.

24

definition of “constraint on the executive” from Gurr’s Polity data set. This is a useful

concept since it measures limitations on the arbitrary use of power by the executive (for

the relevant time period, the monarchy), and is presumably correlated with the security

of property rights for merchants and the control over the monopoly of overseas trade by

the monarchy.31

We follow the Polity IV coding handbook, giving a score 1 to 7 for constraint on the

executive to each country.32 For 1800 and 1850, we use the Polity coding for constraint

on the executive, where available. For earlier periods, we coded these measures ourselves.

The main source for this exercise was Langer (1972), a classic historical encyclopedia,

written with a focus on constitutional events. We supplemented this work with the more

recent edition by Stearns (2001). While there may be disagreement about the precise

values used in particular years, the general level of constraint on the executive does not

appear to be controversial. For example, the absolutist regimes of France, Portugal, and

Spain clearly had much less constraint on the executive than did the Netherlands after

independence or England after the Civil War. AJR (2002b) gives further details and

reports the entire series.

Table 6 documents the differential changes in institutions between Atlantic traders

and other West European nations by estimating an equation similar to (1) with constraint

on the executive as the left-hand side variable. The results show significant

differential improvements in institutions among Atlantic traders, and no evidence of differential

pre-existing trends. Unlike our results when urbanization was the dependent

variable, however, even after the inclusion of Atlantic trade interactions, there is some

evidence of differential West European effects.

Other columns use the same controls and time interactions as in Table 4. Although

the F-statistics show that many of these time interactions are significant, neither Protestantism,

nor wars, nor Roman heritage, nor latitude appear to have led to greater insti-

31The measure of constraint on the executive may not be not ideal for our purposes, however, since

a number of significant constraints on monarchs were imposed by the nobles, and did not necessarily

serve to protect the rights of merchants. For example, in much of the 1500-1750 period, Poland had

a highly constrained executive. But there was relatively little protection for urban merchants–most

of the rights rested with the nobility. For this reason, we modified the definition of constraint on the

executive to create an alternative measure, which we refer to as “protection for capital”. The coding

of this measure depends on the formal rights given to urban merchants, particularly their protection in

the event of a dispute with the nobility or monarch. The results using this measure are similar to the

those using constraint on the executive, and are contained in AJR (2002b).

32A value of 1 means “there are no regular limitations on the executive’s actions,” 3 means “there

are some real but limited restraints on the executive,” 5 means “the executive has more effective

authority than any accountability group, but is subject to substantial constraints by them,” and 7

means “accountability groups have effective authority equal to or greater than the executive in most

activity.” Scores of 2, 4, and 6 are used for intermediate values. See Marshall and Jaggers (2000).

25

tutional change after 1500 (for example, institutions in Protestant countries improved

more rapidly until 1750, and significantly slower thereafter).

Overall, these results suggest that, following the surge in Atlantic trade, there were

greater strides towards better political institutions in nations engaged in Atlantic trade

and colonialism (or in those with a greater potential to engage in Atlantic trade).

4 The Role of Initial Institutions

We now investigate whether, as implied by our hypothesis, it was predominantly societies

with less absolutist initial institutions (and relatedly, those without widespread royal

granted monopoly rights in overseas trade) that took advantage of the opportunities

offered by Atlantic trade. We also investigate the related hypothesis of North and

Thomas (1973) and Jones (1981) that post-1500 developments largely reflect divergence

between societies that had very different political institutions at the turn of the 15th

century. This differs from our hypothesis which emphasizes the interaction between

initial political institutions and Atlantic trade.

To investigate these ideas, we estimate models of the following form:

ujt = dt+δj+ X t≥1600

αt·W Ej ·dt+β·ln ATt·P ATj+ X t≥1500

γt·Ij,1415·dt+η·ln ATt·P ATj ·Ij,1415+εjt,

(3)

where, as before, ujt is the urbanization rate, ln ATt is our measure of Atlantic trade,

P ATj is again either a dummy for Atlantic trader or the Atlantic coastline-to-area ratio,

and Ij,1415 is country j’s initial institutions, calculated as the average of its constraint on

the executive in 1400 and 1500. We choose the average of these two dates to capture the

long-term institutional differences in the pre-1500 period. The γt · Ij,1415 · dt terms allow

any differential economic trends related to differences in initial institutions that would

apply even with no access to the Atlantic. Significant coefficients on these interaction

terms would imply that at least part of the post-1500 developments in Europe reflect

divergent paths taken by countries with different initial institutions, independent of the

effects of Atlantic trade. The table reports the p-value from a joint significance test for

all of these interaction terms. The ln ATt · P ATj term, on the other hand, measures

the effect of Atlantic trade for a given level of institutions. In the table, this term is

evaluated at the lowest score of institutions, i.e., for Ij,1415 = 1, so the coefficient on this

term measures the growth contribution of Atlantic trade and access to the Atlantic for

a society with the worst possible initial institutions.

The variable ln ATt · P ATj · Ij,1415 tests the hypothesis of interest. A significant coef-

ficient η implies that there were divergent paths taken by countries with different initial

26

institutions, but this divergence relates significantly to whether they took advantage of

the opportunities presented by Atlantic trade.

The results are reported in Table 7 using the Atlantic trader dummy for the potential

for Atlantic trade, P ATj (results using the coastline-to-area ratio measure are identical,

and are contained in AJR, 2002b). Panel A presents estimates of equation (3), while

Panel B presents estimates of a similar equation with log income per capita as the

dependent variable. Panel C shows the role of the interaction between initial institutions

and Atlantic trade for the evolution of institutions.

The results in all three panels are similar. The interaction between the aggregate

measure of Atlantic trade and potential for Atlantic trade, ln ATt · P ATj , is generally

significant by itself, and also when entered against the γt · Ij,1415 · dt terms. This shows

that the ability to take advantage of Atlantic trade was of major importance for post-

1500 developments. When we add the triple interaction ln ATt · P ATj · Ij,1415, this

is typically the only significant term.33 For example, the coefficient of 0.021 on this

triple interaction term in column 4 implies that urbanization in an Atlantic trader with

an initial constraint on the executive equal to 3, like the Netherlands, grew by 15.7

percentage points more than urbanization in an Atlantic trader country with the worst

initial institutions, 1 (0.021 × 2 × 3.74 ≈ 0.157, where 3.74 is the change in the log

volume of Atlantic trade between 1500 and 1800).

These results imply that the patterns reported so far are explained almost entirely

by countries with initial institutions constraining rulers taking advantage of the opportunities

presented by Atlantic trade. Although Spain and Portugal benefited from the

transfer of resources from the New World during the 16th century, they neither developed

the political institutions to support economic growth nor experienced sustained

economic development. Our evidence suggests that these differential patterns are closely

related to the fact that they started the post-1500 era with absolutist regimes in control

of overseas activity. On the other hand, it appears that the Italian city-states, which

started with relatively non-absolutist institutions around 1500, did not experience further

economic development because they did not have as easy access to the Atlantic

as Britain and the Netherlands did. Britain and the Netherlands were the economic

winners because they had both relatively good political institutions to start with and

ready access to the Atlantic.

33When the ln ATt · P ATj · Ij,1415 term is included, ln ATt · P ATj has typically a negative and

sometimes significant coefficient–reinforcing the conclusion that nations with absolutist institutions

did not benefit much, or even at all, from the opportunity to trade in the Atlantic. In addition, in three

specifications in Table 7, the interactions between initial institutions and dates after 1600 are jointly

significant, but the coefficients (not shown in the tables) are negative.

27

5 Conclusion

This paper documented a distinctive and interesting fact related to the process of European

growth: between 1500 and 1850, the growth of nations with access to the Atlantic

and of Atlantic ports accounts for most of the differential growth of Western Europe

relative to Eastern Europe. It therefore appears that the Rise of Europe between 1500

and 1850 was largely the rise of Atlantic Europe and the rise of Atlantic ports. This fact

weighs against theories of the origins of European development emphasizing distinctive

European characteristics and purely internal dynamics, but is consistent with those that

give a prominent role to Atlantic trade and de-emphasize the continuation of pre-1500

trends or permanent European characteristics, such as religion, Roman heritage or European

culture. If these factors are important, it must be because of the interaction

between them and the opportunity to trade in the Atlantic.

We suggested that Atlantic trade contributed to European growth through an indirect

institutional channel as well as via its more obvious direct effects. Our hypothesis

is that Atlantic trade generated large profits for commercial interests in favor of institutional

change in countries which met two crucial preconditions: easy access to the Atlantic

and non-absolutist initial institutions. These profits swung the balance of political

power away from the monarchy and induced significant reforms in political institutions,

which introduced more secure property rights and paved the way for further innovations

in economic institutions. With their newly gained property rights, English and Dutch

merchants nations invested more, traded more and spurred economic growth.

Our analysis stopped before West European industrialization, focusing instead on

economic and political developments between the 16th and 19th centuries. Consequently,

we did not investigate why some successful Atlantic nations, like the Dutch, did not industrialize

early, while Britain and some non-Atlantic nations such as Germany did. We

suspect that the answer is related to inter-state competition, “defensive modernization”

responses of certain European nations, and possibly to the adverse effects of oligarchies

on industrialization, but leave further investigation of this issue for future research.

The process of early modern European growth is undoubtedly multi-faceted. We are

aware that our account leaves out many important aspects of the social and economic

development of Western Europe. Our intention is not to offer a mono-causal explanation

for the Rise of Europe, but rather to suggest that Atlantic trade played a major role in

this process. It is our hope that the empirical patterns documented in this paper and

our hypothesis will encourage further research.

28

6 Appendix: Construction of Key Variables

Country-Level and City-Level Urbanization Data. Calculated from the urban population

dataset of Bairoch, Batou and Ch`evre (1988) and country population estimates

from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Details are provided in the Appendix of AJR (2002b).

Trade Measures. AJR (2002b) explains in detail the construction of our Atlantic and

Mediterranean trade volume measures. These series are annual average voyages equivalent

for ships of 400 deadweight tons. The Mediterranean trade estimates are based on

information on Venetian trade levels from Lane (1934), but we also include Genoa, Catalonia,

and other trading centers (Phillips, 1990). They exclude short haul coastal trade

and trade by the British and Dutch–these countries also engaged in Mediterranean

trade as they built their naval power and trading empires after 1600.

Key sources for our Atlantic trade series are de Vries (2001), Tracy (1990), Davis

(1962), and Steensgaard (1974). We have also constructed an alternative Atlantic trade

series based on O’Rourke and Williamson (2002). Robustness results using this series

are reported in AJR (2002b). The growth of our volume-based Atlantic trade series

matches closely with the sum of annual value of Europe-Africa-New World commerce

series in Inikori (2002, Table 4.8, p. 202) and de Vries’ (2001) trade flows with Asia.

Estimates of British Profits from Trade. All figures are approximately in 1600 prices

using the index of building craftsmen’s wages, constructed by Phelps-Brown and Hopkins

(1955), which show a doubling of wages from 1500 to 1600, then a 50% increase from

1600 to 1650, followed by rough stability through 1700 and a further 50% increase during

the 18th century.

1576-1600: Rabb (1967, pp. 61-62) calculates that total profits from privateering in

1585-1603 were $700,000. Dividing by 25 years gives an average of $28,000 per year,

approximately $40,000 in 1600 prices.

1601-1650: Profits for the vertically integrated Dutch East India Company from

1630-1670 were 2.1m guilders (de Vries and van der Woude, p. 447), British trade

with Asia was around a half of Dutch levels in the 17th century (de Vries 2001), and

the guilder-pound exchange rate fluctuated around 10, so total British profits from

Asian trade (including interlopers and suppliers) were likely around $100,000 per annum

(which is consistent with Chaudhuri, 1965). Around $10m was invested between 1600

and 1630 in joint stock companies active in the New World and Africa (Rabb, 1967).

Even when a company failed to show returns, as with the Virginia Company, individual

colonists and their suppliers could earn good profits. Privateering in the 1630s and 1640s

was highly profitable (Craven, 1930). We assume the same level of earnings in the New

World as in the East India trade, i.e., $100,000 per annum, yielding an estimate of

average annual profits of $200,000 in 1600 prices.

1651-1675: From 1650 we use the annual value of export production in British America

from Inikori (2002, p. 181). This was $421,000 in 1651-70 and $2.7m p.a. for

1711-60; we take the average value for 1651-1700 to be $1m. O’Brien’s (1982) numbers

suggest that profits were 50% of import volume, implying profits of $500,000. To this,

29

we add $100,000 p.a. from the East India trade with the same calculation as above,

yielding profits of $600,000 p.a., or approximately $ 500,000 in 1600 prices.

1676-1700: Inikori’s British America trade estimate is $2.7m p.a. for 1711-60; we

assume $2m p.a. for 1676-1700, which implies profits of $1m. Adding East India profits

of $100,000 gives an average annual profit estimate of $1.1m, or $900,000 in 1600 prices.

1701-1750: Inikori’s British America trade estimate is $6.8m for 1761-80; we take

the average value for 1701-50 to be $4m, thus profits of $2m. Adding again profits of

$100,000 from East India gives an average annual profit estimate of $2.1m, about $

1.7m in 1600 prices.

1751-1800: Inikori’s British America trade estimates is $19,545 for 1781-1800, implies

annual profits of around $10m, i.e., double O’Brien’s profit estimate (approximately,

$5m in 1600 prices).

It is worth noting that our profit estimates would be significantly higher prior to 1650

if we also included British and Dutch trade in Asian goods passing through Portugal,

Spain and the Levant (Israel, 1989, Brenner, 2003).

Religion. From Langer (1972) and Stearns (2001), Britain, the Czech Republic, Denmark,

Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland were majority

Protestant in 1600. Germany was largely Protestant, but the balance remained unclear

until the end of the 1600s. The results are robust to coding Germany as Catholic. We

have also tried an alternative specification in which religion is coded directly as Catholic,

Muslim, Orthodox or Protestant, with essentially identical results.

Roman Heritage. From Langer (1972) the following countries had a Roman heritage:

Belgium, Britain, France, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland.

Bulgaria, Greece, Romania, and Yugoslavia had their Roman traditions eradicated by a

long period of Ottoman rule. If they are also coded with Roman heritage, the effect of

this variable is weakened further.

Wars. Kohn (1999) lists the dates of every European wars from about 1000AD, and

a brief explanation of participants, duration, intensity, and outcome. We calculate the

average number of years of war in a time interval before each date in our dataset: for

the preceding 100 years through 1700 and for the preceding 50 years for 1750, 1800, and

1850, excluding purely civil wars and colonial wars outside Europe. Alternative codings

such as dropping “minor” wars do not affect our main results. Kohn (1999) does not

provide reliable information on the wars of Finland and Greece during this period, so

we drop these countries from regressions involving the “wars per year” variable.

Constraint on Executive. This variable is coded using the method of Polity IV as

described in footnote 32. Our primary source in this exercise was the historical encyclopedia

of Langer (1972), supplemented with Stearns (2001). AJR (2002b) provide

more details on our coding, the full series, and robustness checks with some reasonable

alternatives. We also checked our results using the three codings of institutions in De

Long and Shleifer (1993), which are somewhat different from ours, for example awarding

a much better score to feudal systems than does coding based on the Polity criteria.

Using their measures leads to very similar results to those reported in the text.

30

7 References

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2002a) “Reversal

of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income

Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1231-1294.

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2002b) “The

Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth” National

Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 9378.

Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2000) “Political Losers as a Barrier

to Economic Development,” American Economic Review, 90, 126-130.

Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2002) “Economic Backwardness

in Political Perspective,” NBER Working Paper #8831.

Anderson, Perry (1974) Passages from Antiquity to Feudalism, London; NLB

Press.

Ashton, Robert (1960) The Crown and the Money Market, 1603-1640, Oxford

University Press, Oxford.

Ashton, Robert (1979) The City and the Court, New York; Cambridge University

Press.

Ashton, Robert (1996) “Insurgency, Counter-Insurgency and Inaction: Three

Phases in the Role of the City in the Great Rebellion,” in Stephen Porter ed. London

and the Civil War, New York; St. Martin’s Press.

Bairoch, Paul (1988) Cities and Economic Development: From the Dawn of History

to the Present, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Bairoch, Paul (1995) Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes, University

of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Bairoch, Paul, Jean Batou and Pierre Ch`evre (1988) La Population des villes

europ´eenees de 800 `a 1850: Banque de donn´ees et analyse sommaire des r´esultats, Centre

d’histoire ´economique Internationale de l’Uni. de Gen`eve, Libraire Droz, Geneva.

Bean, Richard (1973) “War and the Birth of the Nation State,” The Journal of

Economic History, Volume 33, Issue 1, March, 203-221.

Boxer, Charles R. (1985) Portuguese Conquest and Commerce in Southern Asia,

1500-1750, London, Variorum Reprints.

Braudel, Fernand (1992) Civilization and Capitalism 15th-18th Century; Volume

III The Perspective of the World, Berkeley; University of California Press.

Braudel, Fernand (1995) The Mediterranean and the Mediterranean World in the

Age of Philip II, University of California Press; Berkeley.

Brenner, Robert (1973) “The Civil War Politics of London’s Merchant Community,

Past and Present, 58, 53-107.

Brenner, Robert (2003) Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political

Conflict, and London’s Overseas Traders, 1550-1653, Verso, London.

Brunton, Douglas and D.H. Pennington (1954) Members of the Long Parliament,

London; Allen and Unwin.

31

Cameron, Rondo (1993) A Concise Economic History of the World, New York;

Oxford University Press.

Carruthers, Bruce G. (1996) City of Capital: Politics and Markets in the English

Financial Revolution, Princeton; Princeton University Press.

Chandler, Tertius (1987) Four Thousand Years of Urban Growth: An Historical

Census, St. David’s University Press, Lewiston, N.Y.

Chaudhuri, K. N. (1965) The English East India Company: The Study of an

Early Joint-Stock Company 1600-1640, Frank Cass & Co., London.

Church, W. F. (1969) The Impact of Absolutism on France: National Experience

Under Richelieu, Mazarin, and Louis XIV, John Wiley & Sons, New York.

Cooper, J.P. (1972) “Social and Economic Policies under the Commonwealth,”

in G.E. Aylmer ed. The Interregnum: The Quest for Settlement 1646-1660, London;

Macmillan.

Craven, W. Frank (1930) “The Earl of Warwick, a Speculator in Piracy,” The

Hispanic American Historical Review, Volume 10, Issue 4, November, 457-479.

Davis, Ralph (1962) The Rise of the English Shipping Industry in the Seventeenth

and Eighteenth Centuries, Macmillan, London.

Davis, Ralph (1973a) The Rise of the Atlantic Economies, Ithaca; Cornell University

Press.

Davis, Ralph (1973b) English Overseas Trade 1500-1700, Macmillan; London.

De Long, J. Bradford and Andrei Shleifer (1993) “Princes and Merchants: European

City Growth before the Industrial Revolution,” Journal of Law and Economics,

36, October, 671-702.

Doyle, William (1974)The Parlement of Bordeaux and the End of the Old Regime,

1771-1790, London: Ernest Benn.

Doyle, William (1988) Origins of the French Revolution, Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

de Vries, Jan (1976) The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600-1750,

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

de Vries, Jan (1984) European Urbanization, 1500-1800, Harvard University Press,

Cambridge, Massachusetts.

de Vries, Jan (2001) “Connecting Europe and Asia: A Quantitative Analysis

of the Cape Route Trade, 1497-1795,” unpublished version, University of California at

Berkeley, June. Forthcoming in Dennis Flynn, Arturo Giraldez, and Richard von Glahn,

editors, Monetary History in Global Perspective, London, Ashgate Publishers.

de Vries, Jan and Ad van der Woude (1997) The First Modern Economy:

Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500-1815, New York; Cambridge

University Press.

DK Publishing (1997) World Atlas, New York and London.

Elton, Geoffrey R. (1991) England under the Tudors, 3rd Edition, New York;

Routledge.

32

Engerman, Stanley L. (1972) “The Slave Trade and British Capital Formation in

the Eighteenth Century: A Comment on the Williams Thesis,” Business History Review,

46, 430-443.

Engerman, Stanley L. and O’Brien, Patrick K. (1991) “Exports and the

growth of the British economy from the Glorious Revolution to the Peace of Amiens”, in

Solow, Barbara L. ed. Slavery and the Rise of the Atlantic System, Cambridge University

Press, Cambridge.

Farnell, J.E. (1964) “The Navigation Act of 1651, the First Dutch War, and the

London Merchant Community,” Economic History Review, New Series, 16, 439-545.

Frank, Andre Gunder (1978) Dependent Accumulation and Underdevelopment,

Macmillan, London.

Fritschy, W., Marjolein ’t Hart, and Edwin Horlings (2001) “Continuities

and Discontinuities in Dutch Fiscal History, c.1515-1913,” presented at Economic History

conference in Madrid, 21-23 June.

Fritschy, W. (2003) “A ‘Financial Revolution’ Reconsidered: Public Finance in

Holland During the Dutch Revolt, 1568-1648,” Economic History Review, LVI, 1, pp.57-

89.

Gauci, Perry (2001) The Politics of Trade: The Overseas Merchant in State and

Society, 1660-1720, New York; Oxford University Press.

Grassby, Richard (1969) “The Rate of Profit in Seventeenth-Century England,”

The English Historical Review, Volume 84, Issue 333, October, 721-751.

Grassby, Richard (1995) The Business Community of Seventeenth-Century England,

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Graves, Michael A.R. (2001) The Parliaments of Early Modern Europe, New

York; Longman.

Gurr, Ted Robert (1997) “Polity II: Political Structures and Regime Change,

1800-1986,” Unpublished paper, University of Colorado, Boulder.

Hall, John A. (1985) Powers and Liberties: The Causes and Consequences of the

Rise of the West, Oxford; Blackwell.

Hamilton, Earl J. (1948) “The Role of Monopoly in the Overseas Expansion and

Colonial Trade of Europe before 1800,” American Economic Review, Volume 38, Issue

2, May, 33-53.

’t Hart, Marjolein, Joost Jonker and Jan Luiten van Zanden (1997) A

Financial History of the Netherlands, Cambridge University Press; New York.

Hill, Christopher (1969) From Reformation to Industrial Revolution 1530-1780,

Baltimore; Penguin Books.

Hintze, Otto (1970) [1906] “Military Organization and the Organization of the

State.” In Felix Gilbert (ed.). The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, New York: Oxford

University Press.

Holmes, Geoffrey (1993) The Making of a Great Power: Late Stuart and early

Georgian Britain, New York; Longman.

33

Horwitz, Henry (1978) “The East India Trade, the Politicians, and the Constitution:

1689-1702,” The Journal of British Studies, Vol.17, Issue 2, Spring, 1-18.

Inikori, Joseph E. (2002) Africans and the Industrial Revolution in England: A

Study in International Trade and Economic Development, Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.

Israel, Jonathan I. (1982) The Dutch Republic and the Hispanic World 1606-

1661, Oxford; Oxford University Press.

Israel, Jonathan I. (1989) Dutch Primacy in World Trade, 1585-1740, Oxford;

The Clarendon Press.

Israel, Jonathan I. (1995) The Dutch Republic: Its Rise, Greatness and Fall

1477-1806, New York; Oxford University Press.

Jones, Eric L. (1981) The European Miracle: Environments, Economies, and

Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia, Cambridge University Press, New York.

Keeler, Mary (1954) The Long Parliament, 1640-1641; A Biographical Study of

its Members, Philadelphia; American Philosophical Society.

Kennedy, Paul M. (1987) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic

Change and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000, Random House, New York.

Kohn, George Childs (1999) Dictionary of Wars, Revised Edition, Checkmark

Books (an imprint of Facts on File, Inc.), New York.

Krusell, Per and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull (1996) “Vested Interests in a Theory

of Stagnation and Growth,” Review of Economic Studies, 63, 301-330.

Landes, David S. (1998) The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So

Rich and Some So Poor, W.W. Norton & Co., New York.

Lane, Frederic Chapin (1934), Venetian Ships and Shipbuilding of the Renaissance,

Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

Lang, R. G. (1974) “Social Origins and Social Aspirations of Jacobean London

Merchants,” The Economic History Review, New Series, Volume 27, Issue 1, February,

28-47.

Langer, William L. (1972) An Encyclopedia of World History, Fifth Edition,

Houghton Mifflin Company, Boston.

La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert

W. Vishny (1999) “The Quality of Government,” Journal of Law, Economics and

Organization, V15, N1, 222-279.

Lefebvre, G. (1947) The Coming of the French Revolution, Princeton: Princeton

University Press.

McEvedy, Colin and Richard Jones (1978) Atlas of World Population History,

Facts on File, New York.

Maddison, Angus (2001) The World Economy: A Millenial Perspective, Development

Centre of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD,

Paris.

Manning, Brian (1996) Aristocrats, Plebeians, and Revolution in England, 1640-

1660, Pluto Press; New Haven.

34

Marshall, Monty G. and Keith Jaggers (2000) “Polity IV Project, Political

Regime Characteristics and Transitions 1800-1999, Dataset Users Manual,” Center for

International Development and Conflict Management, University of Maryland.

Morrill, John S. (1993) The Nature of the English Revolution, Longman; New

York.

Neal, Larry (2000) “How It All Began: The Monetary and Financial Architecture

of Europe during the first Global Capital Market, 1648 to 1815,” Financial History

Review, 7:2, 117-140.

North, Douglass C. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History, New

York; W.W. Norton & Co.

North, Douglass C. and Robert P. Thomas (1973) The Rise of the Western

World: A New Economic History, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK.

North, Douglass C. and Barry R. Weingast (1989) “Constitutions and Commitment:

Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century

England, Journal of Economic History, 49, 803-832.

O’Brien, Patrick K. (1982) “European Economic Development: The Contribution

of the Periphery,” Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 35, 1-18.

Olson, Mancur (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation,

and Economic Rigidities, Yale University Press, New Haven and London.

O’Rourke, Kevin H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson (2001) “After Columbus:

Explaining the Global Trade Boom 1500-1800,” Journal of Economic History, volume

62, March.

Parente, Stephen and Edward C. Prescott (1999) “Monopoly Rights as Barriers

to Riches,” American Economic Review, 89, 1216-1233.

Parker, Geoffrey (1977) The Dutch Revolt, Penguin Books, Harmonsworth, England.

Parker, Geoffrey (1988) The Military Revolution: Military Innovation and the

Rise of the West, 1500-1800, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Parrott, David (2001) Richelieu’s Army. War, government and society in France,

1624-1642. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

Parry, James H. (1966) The Spanish Seaborne Empire, Berkeley; University of

California Press.

Pearl, Valerie (1961) London and the Outbreak of the Puritan Revolution; City

Government and National Politics, 1625-43, London; Oxford University Press.

Phelps Brown, E.H. and Sheila V. Hopkins (1955) “Seven Centuries of Building

Wages,” Economica, New Series, Vol. 22, No.87, August, 195-206.

Phillips, Carla Rahn (1990), “The growth and composition of trade in the Iberian

empires, 1450-1750,” in The Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-Distance Trade in the

Early Modern World, 1350-1750, edited by James D. Tracy, Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.

Pincus, Steven (2002) “Civic Republicanism and Political Economy in an Age of

Revolution: Law, Politics, and Economics in the Revolution of 1688-89,” Unpublished,

35

Department of History, University of Chicago.

Rabb, Theodore K. (1967) Enterprise and Empire: Merchant and Gentry Investment

in the Expansion of England, 1575-1630, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

Rabb, Theodore K. (1998) Jacobean Gentleman: Sir Edwin Sandys, 1561-1629,

Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Rajan, Raghuram G. and Zingales, Luigi (2003) Saving Capitalism from the

Capitalists: Unleashing the Power of Financial Markets to Create Wealth and Spread

Opportunity, Crown Publishing Group, New York.

Richardson, R.C. (1998) The Debate on the English Revolution, 3rd Edition,

Manchester; University of Manchester Press.

Rodger, N.A.M. (1997) The Safeguard of the Sea: A Naval History of Britain,

660-1649, W.W. Norton, New York.

Rogowski, Ronald (1989) Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade affects Domestic

Political Alignments, Princeton University Press, Princeton.

Russell, Conrad (1990) The Causes of the English Civil War, New York; Oxford

University Press.

Sacks, David H. (1991) The Widening Gate: Bristol and the Atlantic Economy,

1450-1700, Berkeley; University of California Press.

Scoville, Warren C. (1960) The Persecution of Huguenots and French Economic

Development, 1680-1720, Berkeley: University of California Press.

Sharpe, Kevin (1992) The Personal Rule of Charles I, New Haven; Yale University

Press.

Stasavage, David (2003) Public Debt and the Birth of the Democratic State:

France and Great Britain 1688-1789, New York; Cambridge University Press.

Stearns, Peter N. (2001) The Encyclopedia of World History, Sixth Edition,

Houghton Mifflin Company, Boston.

Steensgaard, N. (1974) The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century,

Chicago, 1974.

Stone, Lawrence (1972) The Causes of the English Revolution, 1529-1642, New

York; Routledge.

Tilly, Charles (1990) Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1990, Cambridge

MA; Basil Blackwell.

Thompson, I. A. A. (1994) “Castile: Absolutism, Constitutionalism and Liberty,”

in Philip T. Hoffman and Kathryn Norberg eds. Fiscal Crisis, Liberty and Representative

Government, Stanford; Stanford University Press.

Tracy, James D. (1985) A Financial Revolution in the Habsburg Netherlands,

University of California Press; Berkeley.

Tracy, James D. (1990) The Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-Distance Trade in

the Early Modern World, 1350-1750, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Tracy, James D. (2001) “Keeping the Wheels of War Turning: Revenues of the

Province of Holland, 1572-1619” in Graham Darby The Origins and Development of the

Dutch Revolt, Routledge; New York.

36

van der Wee, Herman (1993) “The Economy as a Factor in the Revolt of the

Southern Netherlands” in Herman van der Wee, The Low Countries in the Early Modern

World, Variorum: Brookfield VT.

van Zanden, Jan Luiten (1993) The Rise and Decline of Holland’s Economy,

University of Manchester Press; Manchester.

Wallerstein, Immanuel M. (1974-1980) The Modern World-System, 3 Volumes,

Academic Press, New York.

Weber, Max (1993) [1905] The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism,

Routledge, London.

Williams, Eric E. (1944) Capitalism and Slavery, University of North Carolina

Press, Chapel Hill.

World Bank (1999) World Development Indicators, CD-Romand Book, Washington

DC.

37

Whole

Sample,

unweighted

Whole

Sample,

weighted

Atlantic

Western

Europe

Non-

Atlantic

Western

Europe

Eastern

Europe Asia

Urbanization in 1300 6.6 9.9 8.0 10.0 4.1 11.0

(5.2) (3.2) (2.8) (6.1) (3.3) (0.7)

Urbanization in 1400 7.6 10.3 8.5 12.1 3.9 11.1

(9.5) (3.6) (2.4) (10.0) (1.5) (0.5)

Urbanization in 1500 8.3 10.6 10.1 11.4 4.0 11.5

(7.6) (3.4) (5.3) (6.8) (1.8) (0.7)

Urbanization in 1600 9.6 11.7 13.6 14.0 4.4 12.0

(7.6) (4.0) (7.6) (8.8) (2.7) (0.7)

Urbanization in 1700 10.7 11.2 14.5 13.1 3.7 11.6

(8.5) (4.1) (6.8) (8.1) (2.2) (0.7)

Urbanization in 1800 14.1 10.3 19.8 16.9 7.0 8.9

(9.1) (4.9) (7.9) (7.5) (3.3) (1.4)

GDP per capita in 1500 627.54 608.3 721.46 850.73 506.94 575

(159.3) (118.0) (31.1) (217.1) (78.2) (35.4)

GDP per capita in 1600 740.73 630.5 916.31 908.22 578.29 576.8

(225.6) (144.2) (149.3) (167.3) (112.3) (35.3)

GDP per capita in 1700 862.12 622.2 1079.21 980.82 636.0 574.2

(348.4) (208.1) (321.4) (128.2) (136.1) (35.3)

GDP per capita in 1820 988.00 691.7 1321.95 1095.40 719.5 575.5

(373.6) (264.5) (348.7) (125.3) (174.9) (45.7)

Constraint on Executive in 1500 1.67 1.73 1.80 1.99 1.46

(0.76) (0.79) (0.59) (0.99) (0.79)

Constraint on Executive in 1600 1.67 1.53 1.65 1.54 1.45

(1.01) (0.84) (1.15) (0.59) (0.79)

Constraint on Executive in 1700 1.83 1.52 1.96 1.41 1.30

(1.31) (1.17) (1.71) (0.94) (0.76)

Constraint on Executive in 1800 2.25 2.18 4.16 1.90 1.00

(1.82) (1.83) (1.72) (1.78) (0.00)

Atlantic Coastline-to-Area 0.0057 0.0014 0.0118 0.0026 0.00 0.00

(0.0117) (0.0065) (0.0181) (0.0052)

Weighted by population

First column is unweighted means; other columns are mean values weighted by total population in

year indicated, from McEvedy and Jones. Standard deviation is in parentheses. There are 24 European

countries in these data. Atlantic Western Europe is England, France, the Netherlands, Portugal, and

Spain. Non-Atlantic Western Europe is Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy,

Norway, Sweden and Switzerland. Eastern Europe is Albania, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Greece,

Hungary, Poland, Romania, Russia, and Serbia. Asia is India and China. Urbanization for Europe is

percent population towns with population of at least 5,000 at some time between 800 and 1800, from

Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre for Europe; comparable data for Asia are from Bairoch. GDP per capita is

from Maddison. Constraint on executive is on a scale from 1 to 7, where a higher score indicates more

constraints; this is coded using the Polity IV methodology, as explained in the text. We have not coded

constraint on the executive for Asia. Atlantic Coast-to-Area includes those parts of Germany, Denmark

and Norway that are on the North Sea. For more detailed definitions and sources see Appendix Table 1.

Table 1

Descriptive Statistics

Panel, 1300-1850 Panel, 1000-1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850,

unweighted

Panel, 1300-

1850, with Asia

Panel, 1300-

1850, without

Britain

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850,

unweighted

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

p-value for Western Europe x [0.00] [0.00] [0.45] [0.10] [0.80] [0.00] [0.12] [0.09] [0.01] [0.78]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1500 0.016 0.0086 0.055 0.014 0.018 0.50 0.38 0.75

(0.021) (0.019) (0.026) (0.022) (0.016) (0.68) (0.65) (0.87)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1600 0.006 -0.004 0.0495 0.0054 0.0085 0.21 0.03 0.94

(0.023) (0.021) (0.028) (0.028) (0.018) (0.68) (0.64) (0.94)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1700 0.032 0.022 0.071 0.032 0.024 1.81 1.64 2.01

(0.021) (0.019) (0.028) (0.026) (0.016) (0.63) (0.58) (0.94)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1750 0.032 0.022 0.073 0.032 0.023 2.16 1.99 2.60

(0.021) (0.018) (0.028) (0.025) (0.015) (0.62) (0.57) (0.94)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1800 0.048 0.038 0.110 0.047 0.028 3.30 3.12 3.76

(0.019) (0.017) (0.028) (0.023) (0.015) (0.57) (0.51) (0.94)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1850 0.085 0.076 0.115 0.084 0.043 5.05 4.88 4.67

(0.018) (0.016) (0.028) (0.022) (0.014) (0.51) (0.44) (0.94)

R-Squared 0.87 0.85 0.89 0.87 0.82 0.84 0.93 0.94 0.92 0.83

Number of Observations 192 240 192 240 192 208 184 192 240 192

p-value for Western Europe x [0.00] [0.00] [0.35] [0.06] [0.83] [0.00] [0.11] [0.16] [0.02] [0.81]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 0.011 0.0083 0.016 0.011 0.005 0.75 0.65 0.62

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.0024) (0.0020) (0.0034) (0.0029) (0.0018) (0.07) (0.06) (0.11)

R-Squared 0.87 0.85 0.88 0.86 0.81 0.84 0.92 0.92 0.90 0.82

Number of Observations 192 240 192 240 192 208 184 192 240 192

Table 2

Atlantic Trade and Urbanization

Dependent variable is country-level urbanization

Standard errors are in parentheses. Panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies; regressions are weighted unless otherwise stated. Weighted

regressions use total population in each year as weights, from McEvedy and Jones. Dependent variable is level of urbanization (percent of population living in

towns which had at least 5,000 population at some point between 800 and 1800) in each country in each year. Urbanization in Europe is from Bairoch, Batou

and Chèvre, and urbanization in Asia is from Bairoch. We report results with two different measures of potential for Atlantic trade: a dummy for whether a

country was an Atlantic trader (one for Britain, the Netherlands, France, Spain and Portugal; zero for all others) in columns 3, 4, 5, 6 and 7; and the ratio of

Atlantic coastline to area for the Atlantic trader countries plus Belgium, Denmark, Germany, Ireland, and Norway (columns 8, 9, and 10). Column 6 includes

the available data on Asia (just for India and China) and column 7 drops the data for Britain. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average number of voyages

per year. For more detailed data definitions and sources see Appendix Table 1.

Potential for Atlantic Trade is measured by:

Atlantic coastline-to-area Atlantic trader dummy

Panel A: flexible specification

Panel B: structured specification

Panel, 1500-1820 Panel, 1500-1870

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1820,

unweighted

Panel, 1500-

1820, with Asia

Panel, 1500-

1820, without

Britain

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1820,

unweighted

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

p-value for Western Europe x [0.44] [0.05] [0.92] [0.23] [0.17] [0.01] [0.89] [0.97] [0.58] [0.31]

year dummies, 1600-1820 or -1870

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1600 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.14 0.13 4.43 4.46 3.42

(0.07) (0.11) (0.07) (0.13) (0.07) (2.42) (3.61) (2.21)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1700 0.18 0.19 0.21 0.18 0.14 8.84 8.80 6.32

(0.07) (0.10) (0.07) (0.12) (0.06) (2.27) (3.40) (2.21)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1820 0.27 0.27 0.18 0.27 0.20 12.03 11.89 8.06

(0.06) (0.10) (0.07) (0.11) (0.06) (2.10) (3.14) (2.21)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1870 0.22 15.84

(0.09) (2.93)

R-Squared 0.94 0.94 0.96 0.95 0.96 0.92 0.96 0.96 0.96 0.96

Number of Observations 96 120 96 120 96 104 92 96 120 96

p-value for Western Europe x [0.44] [0.05] [0.92] [0.48] [0.14] [0.01] [0.88] [0.99] [0.54] [0.23]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 0.069 0.040 0.047 0.069 0.051 3.21 3.18 2.22

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.016) (0.017) (0.018) (0.028) (0.015) (0.53) (0.50) (0.58)

R-Squared 0.94 0.94 0.96 0.95 0.96 0.92 0.96 0.96 0.96 0.96

Number of Observations 96 120 96 120 96 104 92 96 120 96

Atlantic coastline-to-area

Standard errors are in parentheses. Panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies; regressions are weighted unless otherwise stated. Weighted

regressions use total population in each year as weights, from McEvedy and Jones. Dependent variable is log GDP per capita, from Maddison. We report

results with two different measures of potential for Atlantic trade: a dummy for whether a country was an Atlantic trader (one for Britain, the Netherlands,

France, Spain and Portugal; zero for all others) in columns 3, 4, 5, 6 and 7; and the ratio of Atlantic coastline to area for the Atlantic trader countries plus

Belgium, Denmark, Germany, Ireland, and Norway (columns 8, 9, and 10). Column 6 includes the available data on Asia (just for India and China) and

column 7 drops the data for Britain. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average number of voyages per year. For more detailed data definitions and sources

see Appendix Table 1.

Atlantic trader dummy

Panel A: flexible specification

Panel B: structured specification

Table 3

Atlantic Trade and GDP per capita

Dependent Variable is country-level log GDP per capita

Potential for Atlantic Trade is measured by:

Panel, 1300-1850,

controlling for

religion

Panel, 1300 to

1850,

controlling for

wars

Panel, 1300 to

1850,

controlling for

Roman

heritage

Panel, 1300 to

1850,

controlling for

latitude

Panel, 1500-1820,

controlling for

religion

Panel, 1500 to

1820,

controlling for

wars

Panel, 1500 to 1820,

controlling for

Roman heritage

Panel, 1500 to

1820, controlling

for latitude

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

p-value for Western Europe x [0.73] [0.49] [0.49] [0.09] [0.24] [0.91] [0.15] [0.85]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Atlantic Trader Dummy x 0.013 0.011 0.011 0.011 0.089 0.070 0.125 0.078

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.013) (0.017) (0.017) (0.015)

p-value for Protestant x Year [0.05] [0.00]

Wars per year in preceding century -0.0006 0.075

(0.008) (0.029)

p-value for Roman Heritage x Year [0.89] [0.00]

p-value for Latitude x Year [0.11] [0.00]

R-Squared 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.97 0.95 0.97 0.97

Number of Observations 192 176 192 192 96 88 96 96

p-value for Western Europe x [0.19] [0.26] [0.39] [0.09] [0.99] [0.98] [0.71] [0.81]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Coastline-to-area x 0.79 0.76 0.75 0.78 2.78 3.33 3.32 2.96

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.08) (0.08) (0.07) (0.07) (0.54) (0.56) (0.54) (0.56)

p-value for Protestant x Year [0.51] [0.05]

Wars per year in preceding century 0.0082 0.032

(0.007) (0.026)

p-value for Roman Heritage x Year [0.77] [0.32]

p-value for Latitude x Year [0.52] [0.38]

R-Squared 0.93 0.93 0.92 0.93 0.97 0.96 0.97 0.97

Number of Observations 192 176 192 192 96 88 96 96

Protestant is a dummy for whether country was majority Protestant in 1600. Protestant x Year is the Protestant dummy interacted

with year dummies for 1600 and after. Wars per year are in preceding century through 1700, 1700-1750 for 1750, 1750-1800 for 1800

and 1800-1850 for 1850. Roman heritage is dummy for whether country was in the Roman empire; this is interacted with year dummies

for 1600 and after. Latitude is distance from the equator for capital city of this country today; this is interacted with year dummies for

1600 and after. For more detailed data definitions and sources see Appendix Table 1.

Standard errors are in parentheses. Weighted panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies. Weights are total

population of country in each year from McEvedy and Jones. Dependent variable in Panels A and C is level of urbanization (percent of

population living in towns with more than 5,000 population.) Urbanization in Europe is from Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre. Dependent

variable in Panels B and D is log GDP per capita, from Maddison. Panels A and B use the Atlantic trader dummy as the measure of

potential for Atlantic trade (one for Britain, France, Spain, Portugal and the Netherlands, zero for all others). Panels C and D use the

ratio of Atlantic coastline to area. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average number of voyages per year.

Panel C: Dependent Variable is Level of

Urbanization Panel D: Dependent Variable is Log GDP per capita

Table 4

Robustness Checks

Using Atlantic trader dummy measure of Potential for Atlantic Trade

Using Atlantic coastline-to-area measure of Potential for Atlantic Trade

Panel B: Dependent Variable is Log GDP per capita

Panel A: Dependent Variable is Level of

Urbanization

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850, weighted

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850,

unweighted

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850,

weighted

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850,

unweighted

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850, weighted,

without London and

Amsterdam

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850, weighted,

with full set of country

x year interactions

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850, with

Asia

Balanced Panel,

1300-1850; with

Mediterranean and

Atlantic ports

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

p-value for Western Europe x [0.34] [0.05] [0.30] [0.16] [0.28] [0.30] [0.41] [0.32]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Atlantic Port x 1500 -0.04 -0.05 0.027 0.048 -0.008 -0.072 -0.03 -0.05

(0.19) (0.20) (0.17) (0.16) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20) (0.19)

Atlantic Port x 1600 0.36 0.46 0.41 0.43 0.41 0.36 0.36 0.40

(0.16) (0.20) (0.14) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.16) (0.16)

Atlantic Port x 1700 0.71 0.62 0.76 0.76 0.297 0.47 0.71 0.74

(0.14) (0.20) (0.13) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.15) (0.15)

Atlantic Port x 1750 0.70 0.71 0.79 0.89 0.26 0.46 0.7 0.72

(0.14) (0.20) (0.13) (0.16) (0.16) (0.16) (0.15) (0.14)

Atlantic Port x 1800 0.79 0.92 0.95 1.10 0.32 0.57 0.799 0.84

(0.14) (0.20) (0.12) (0.16) (0.15) (0.15) (0.14) (0.14)

Atlantic Port x 1850 1.09 1.00 1.19 1.23 0.48 0.46 1.09 1.10

(0.13) (0.20) (0.12) (0.16) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14) (0.13)

p-value for Mediterranean Port x [0.19]

year dummies, 1500-1850

R-Squared 0.92 0.79 0.92 0.80 0.89 0.95 0.94 0.92

Number of Observations 1544 1544 1544 1544 1528 1544 1624 1544

p-value for Western Europe x [0.23] [0.04] [0.23] [0.10] [0.31] [0.33] [0.20] [0.20]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Volume of Atlantic Trade 0.17 0.16 0.17 0.16 0.065 0.078 0.27 0.17

x Atlantic Port (0.02) (0.02) (0.017) (0.024) (0.019) (0.018) (0.017) (0.017)

p-value for Mediterranean Port x [0.14]

year dummies, 1500-1850

R-Squared 0.92 0.79 0.92 0.79 0.89 0.95 0.88 0.92

Number of Observations 1544 1544 1544 1544 1528 1544 1624 1544

Table 5

Growth of Atlantic Ports

p g p g y y ;g pp y y g pp

Dependent variable is log city population, from Bairoch, Batou, and Chèvre. All columns report balanced panel regressions for 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800 and 1850, using only

cities for which we have data in all 8 time periods. The Atlantic port dummy equals one for a city used as an Atlantic port. Potential Atlantic ports are all ports that could have been used for Atlantic

trade and include Atlantic ports plus ports in Belgium, Germany, and Ireland (there are no potential Atlantic ports in Denmark or Norway in our balanced panel). Volume of Atlantic Trade is log

average voyages per year; this is multiplied by the Atlantic port dummy (or by the potential Atlantic port dummy); the coefficient on this interaction term is multiplied by 100. Year dummies are

included for all years from 1400. Western Europe x year dummies are included for all years from 1600. For a list of Atlantic ports and potential Atlantic ports, see the Appendix of Acemgolu,

Johnson, and Robinson (2002b).

Dependent Variable is log city population

Atlantic Port Potential Atlantic Port Atlantic Port

Panel A: flexible specification

Panel B: structured specification

Panel, 1300-

1850 Panel, 1300-1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850,

controlling for

religion

Panel, 1300 to

1850,

controlling for

wars

Panel, 1300 to

1850, controlling

for Roman

heritage

Panel, 1300 to

1850, controlling

for latitude

Panel, 1300 to 1850,

using Atlantic

coastline-to-area

measure of potential

for Atlantic trade

Panel, 1300 to 1850,

using Atlantic

coastline-to-area

measure of potential

for Atlantic trade

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

p-value for Western Europe x [0.00] [0.35] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.26] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]

year dummies, 1600-1850

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1500 -0.42 -20.83

(0.47) (22.94)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1600 -0.14 10.94

(0.52) (22.91)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1700 0.29 62.12

(0.48) (21.14)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1750 0.32 81.45

(0.46) (20.78)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1800 2.07 79.81

(0.44) (18.97)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 1850 2.96 72.25

(0.41) (17.13)

Potential for Atlantic Trade x 0.42 0.45 0.43 0.39 0.43 12.99

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (2.31)

p-value for Protestant x year effect [0.00]

Wars per year in preceding century -0.04

(0.20)

p-value for Roman Heritage x Year [0.05]

p-value for Latitude x Year [0.49]

R-Squared 0.75 0.85 0.81 0.84 0.81 0.82 0.81 0.81 0.79

Number of Observations 192 192 192 192 176 192 192 192 192

Table 6

Atlantic Trade and Institutions

Dependent Variable is Constraint on Executive

Standard errors are in parentheses. Weighted panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies. Weights are total population in each

country in each year, from McEvedy and Jones. Dependent variable is constraint on executive, which ranges from 1 to 7 where a higher score

indicates more constraints on arbitary action by the executive. All columns use the Atlantic trader dummy (one for Britain, France, Spain, Portugal

and the Netherlands; zero for all others) as the measure of potential for Atlantic trade, apart from columns 8 and 9 which use the ratio of Atlantic

coastline to area (including Atlantic traders plus Belgium, Denmark, Germany, Ireland and Norway). Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average

number of voyages per year. Protestant is a dummy for whether country was majority Protestant in 1600. Protestant x Year is the Protestant dummy

interacted with year dummies for 1600 and after. Wars per year are for the preceding century through 1700, 1700-1750 for 1750, 1750-1800 for 1800

and 1800-1850 for 1850. Roman heritage is dummy for whether country was in the Roman empire; this is interacted with year dummies for 1600 and

after. Latitude is distance from the equator for capital city of this country today; this is interacted with year for 1600 and after.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850,

unweighted

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850

Panel, 1000-

1850,

unweighted

Atlantic Trader Dummy x 0.011 0.011 -0.0090 -0.0026 0.0082 0.0084 -0.012 -0.009

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.002) (0.002) (0.0049) (0.0062) (0.0020) (0.0020) (0.004) (0.005)

p-value for Initial Institutions x year [0.61] [0.51] [0.71] [0.85] [0.12] [0.08] [0.42] [0.92]

(1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, 1850)

Volume of Atlantic Trade x Initial Institutions 0.021 0.017 0.021 0.022

x Atlantic Trader Dummy (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004)

R-Squared 0.87 0.88 0.89 0.90 0.83 0.86 0.86 0.87 0.87 0.81

Number of Observations 192 192 192 192 192 240 240 240 240 240

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1820

Panel, 1500-

1820,

unweighted

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1870

Panel, 1500-

1870,

unweighted

Atlantic Trader Dummy x 0.069 0.068 -0.068 -0.079 0.004 0.039 -0.122 -0.110

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.016) (0.016) (0.028) (0.028) (0.017) (0.017) (0.030) (0.028)

p-value for Initial Institutions x year [0.40] [0.31] [0.004] [0.08] [0.66] [0.64] [0.01] [0.58]

(1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, 1850)

Volume of Atlantic Trade x Initial Institutions 0.14 0.12 0.16 0.11

x Atlantic Trader Dummy (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02)

R-Squared 0.94 0.96 0.96 0.97 0.97 0.95 0.95 0.95 0.96 0.96

Number of Observations 96 96 96 96 96 120 120 120 120 120

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850

Panel, 1300-

1850,

unweighted

Panel, 1500-

1850

Panel, 1500-

1850

Panel, 1500-

1850

Panel, 1500-

1850

Panel, 1500-

1850,

unweighted

Atlantic Trader Dummy x 0.42 0.42 -0.001 -0.096 0.35 0.34 -0.11 -0.15

Volume of Atlantic Trade (0.06) (0.06) (0.12) (0.12) (0.05) (0.05) (0.10) (0.09)

p-value for Initial Institutions x year [0.27] [0.14] [0.008] [0.69] [0.43] [0.33] [0.01] [0.95]

(1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, 1850)

Volume of Atlantic Trade x Initial Institutions 0.44 0.26 0.47 0.29

x Atlantic Trader Dummy (0.11) (0.09) (0.09) (0.07)

R-Squared 0.76 0.81 0.82 0.84 0.76 0.72 0.77 0.78 0.70 0.71

Number of Observations 192 192 192 192 192 240 240 240 240 240

Table 7

Interaction Between Initial Institutions and Atlantic Trade

Using Atlantic trader dummy as measure of Atlantic trade

Standard errors are in parentheses. Weighted panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies. Weights are total population in each country in each year,

from McEvedy and Jones. Dependent variable is urbanization in Panel A, log GDP per capita in Panel B, and constraint on the executive in Panel C. Western

Europe dummies interacted with years (from 1600) are included in all columns, but not reported to save space. Urbanization in Europe is from Bairoch, Batou and

Chèvre, and urbanization in Asia is from Bairoch. Log GDP per capita is from Maddison. Constraint on the executive is coded from Langer; initial institutions are

the average of institutions in 1400 and 1500. We use the Atlantic trader dummy as the measure of potential for Atlantic trade. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log

average number of voyages per year and is demeaned. Main effects are evaluated at initial institutions equal to one. For data definitions and sources see Appendix

Table 1.

Panel A: Dependent Variable is Urbanization

Panel B: Dependent Variable is Log GDP per capita

Panel C: Dependent Variable is Constraint on the Executive

Variable Description Source

Log GDP per capita in 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820 and 1870 Logarithm of GDP per capita. Maddison (2001)

Population in 1000, 1200, 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700,

1750, 1800, and 1850.

Total population. McEvedy and Jones (1978)

Urban population in 1000, 1200, 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600,

1700, 1750, 1800, and 1850.

Population living in urban areas. Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre (1988), as described in the appendix. We use Bairoch

(1988) for urbanization in Asia and Chandler for Asian city population.

Atlantic and Mediteranean ports City that is on the Atlantic or Mediteranean Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre (1988) for cities; location from DK Publishing (1997).

Ratio of Atlantic coastline to area Length of Atlantic coastline divided by land area. Both assume modern borders. Atlantic coastline includes the

whole coast of Portugal, Ireland, Belgium, the Netherlands, and Britain. It also includes half the coastline of Spain,

two-thirds the coastline of France, half the coastline of Germany, one quarter the coastline of Denmark, and half the

coastline of Norway.

Coastline is from Integrated Coastline Management (on the web.) Land area is from

the World Bank, World Development Indicators, CD-Rom, 1999.

Dummy for Atlantic trader Equals one for Britain, France, the Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain. Coded by authors based on composition of Atlantic trade. See AJR (2002b) for details.

Dummy for Atlantic port Equals one for a city that was used as an Atlantic port; zero otherwise. Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre (1988) for cities; location from DK Publishing (1997).

Dummy for potential Atlantic port Equals one for a city that is on the Atlantic; zero otherwise. Bairoch, Batou and Chèvre (1988) for cities; location from DK Publishing (1997).

Volume of Atlantic Trade Average voyages per year equivalent. See Appendix. AJR(2002b) provides full details.

Constraint on executive in 1800, 1850, 1960, 1970, 1990 and

intervening years.

A seven category scale, from 1 to 7, with a higher score indicating more constraints. Score of 1 indicates unlimited

authority; score of 3 indicates slight to moderate limitations; score of 5 indicates substantial limitations; score of 7

indicates executive parity or subordination. Scores of 2, 4, and 6 indicate intermediate values.

Polity IV dataset, downloaded from Inter-University Consortium for Political and

Social Research. Variable described in Gurr 1997.

Constraint on executive from 1000 to 1800 A seven category scale, from 1 to 7, with a higher score indicating more constraints. Score of 1 indicates unlimited

authority; score of 3 indicates slight to moderate limitations; score of 5 indicates substantial limitations; score of 7

indicates executive parity or subordination. Scores of 2, 4, and 6 indicate intermediate values.

Coded by authors from Langer (1972); see appendix for more details.

Religion Variables Majority religion of city or country. Coded by authors from Langer (1972).

Roman heritage Coded equal to one for countries that were part of the Roman empire and not subsequently part of the Ottoman

empire.

Coded by authors from Langer (1972).

Wars per year Number of years of war in preceding 50 or 100 years. Civil wars and colonial wars outside Europe are excluded. Coded by authors from Kohn (1999)

Latitude Absolute value of the latitude of the country, scaled to take values between 0 and 1, where 0 is the equator. Country data from La Porta et al (1999). City data from Bairoch, Batou and Chevre

(1988).

Appendix Table 1

Variable Definitions and Sources

Figure 1A

Figure 1B

Urbanization rates

weighted by population

0

5

10

15

20

25

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Western Europe Eastern Europe Asia

Urbanization rates

weighted by population

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Atlantic traders Western Europe not Atlantic traders Eastern Europe

Figure 2A

Figure 2B

GDP per capita from 1500

weighted by population

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

1500 1600 1700 1820 1870

Atlantic traders Western Europe not Atlantic traders Eastern Europe

GDP per capita from 1500

weighted by population

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

1500 1600 1700 1820 1870

Western Europe Eastern Europe Asia

Figure 3

Vo lume o f Atlantic and Mediterranean Trade

(vo yage equivalents per year)

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800

Atlantic voyages per year Mediterranean voyages per year

Figure 4A

Figure 4B

Average of log city population in Atlantic ports, West European cities that are not Atlantic ports, and

Eastern Europe (balanced panel)

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

West European cities Atlantic ports East European cities

Average of log population in Atlantic ports, Mediterranean ports, and West European cities that are

not ports (balanced panel)

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Inland West European cities Atlantic ports Mediterranean ports

Figure 5A

Figure 5B

Average of log population in Iberian Atlantic ports and other cities

(balanced panel)

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Iberian cities, not Atlantic ports

Iberian Atlantic ports

Inland West European cities

Average of log population in British Atlantic ports and other cities

(balanced panel)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

British cities not Atlantic ports

British Atlantic ports

Inland West European cities


This content was originally posted on Y! Answers, a Q&A website that shut down in 2021.
Loading...